WP/16/189
The Effectiveness of Monetary Policy in Small Open
Economies: An Empirical Investigation
By Keyra Primus
© 2016 International Monetary Fund WP/16/189
IMF Working Paper
Middle East and Central Asia Department
The Effectiveness of Monetary Policy in Small Open Economies: An Empirical
Investigation
Prepared by Keyra Primus
Authorized for distribution by Mark Horton
September 2016
Abstract
This paper examines the relative effectiveness of the use of indirect and direct monetary
policy instruments in Barbados, Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago, by estimating a
restricted Vector Autoregressive model with Exogenous Variables (VARX). The study
assumes that the central bank conducts monetary policy using a Taylor-type rule and it
evaluates the effects of a reserve requirement policy. The results show that although a
positive shock to the policy interest rate has a direct effect on commercial banks' interest
rates, there is a weak transmission to the real variables. Furthermore, an increase in the
required reserve ratio is successful in reducing private sector credit and excess reserves,
while at the same time alleviating pressures on the exchange rate. The findings therefore
indicate that central banks in small open economies should consider using reserve
requirements as a complement to interest rate policy, to achieve their macroeconomic
objectives.
JEL Classification Numbers: E43, E52, E58
Keywords: Reserve Requirements, Macroeconometric Model, Small Open Economies
Author’s E-Mail Address: [email protected]
I am grateful for very helpful discussions and comments from Pierre-Richard Agénor, Winston Moore, Mark
Horton, Tarron Khemraj, Issouf Samake, Reshma Mahabir, Franka Primus, DeLisle Worrell, Darrin Downes
and Trevor Robert.
IMF Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to
elicit comments and to encourage debate. The views expressed in IMF Working Papers are
those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive Board,
or IMF management.
2
Contents
I. Introduction ……………………………………………………………........... 3
II. The Caribbean Context …………………….…………………………........... 5
III. Econometric Methodology ………………………………………………....... 7
A. The Standard VARX Model ..…………………………………………....... 8
B. A VARX for Barbados, Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago ..………........... 8
B.1. Fully Interactive Variables …...…………………………..………......... 8
B.2. Partially Interactive Variables ……….………………..………........... 9
B.3. Strictly Exogenous Variables .……………….…………………......... 11
B.4. Relationship of Variables …...……………….…………………......... 11
IV. Econometric Results ……………………………………………………........ 13
A. Shock to the Policy Rate ………………………………………………….. 13
A.1. Barbados …………………………………………………….............. 14
A.2. Jamaica ……………………………………………………................ 15
A.3. Trinidad and Tobago ……………………………………………....... 16
B. Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio ….………………………........... 18
B.1. Barbados ………………………………………………….................. 18
B.2. Jamaica ………………………………………………….................... 19
B.3. Trinidad and Tobago ……………………………………………....... 20
V. Conclusion and Policy Implications …………………………………............ 21
References ……………………………………………………………......................... 23
Table 1. Unit Root and Seasonality Tests ……….……………………………………….. 26
List of Figures
1 Barbados: Shock to the Policy Interest Rate, IRFs ……….……………………….…. 27
2 Barbados: Shock to the Policy Interest Rate, VDs .…...………………………….….. 28
3 Barbados: Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio, IRFs ………..…………….…... 29
4 Barbados: Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio, VDs ………….…………….. 30
5 Jamaica: Shock to the Policy Interest Rate, IRFs ………………………………......... 31
6 Jamaica: Shock to the Policy Interest Rate, VDs ………………………….……..….. 32
7 Jamaica: Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio, IRFs ……………….……….….. 33
8 Jamaica: Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio, VDs …………………….….….. 34
9 Trinidad and Tobago: Shock to the Policy Interest Rate, IRFs …………….….….…. 35
10 Trinidad and Tobago: Shock to the Policy Interest Rate, VDs ………………...……. 36
11 Trinidad and Tobago: Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio, IRFs ..….....…… 37
12 Trinidad and Tobago: Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio, VDs ………….…... 38
I. Introduction
Monetary policy is a key element of macroeconomic management and its ectiveness is an
important issue in economic policy analysis. To successfully conduct monetary policy, policy-
makers must have an accurate assessment of the ects of their policies on the economy. A
crucial element that can determine how monetary conditions can in‡uence the economic perfor-
mance of a country is the choice of the policy instrument used. In developed countries, which
have more sophisticated nancial systems, there is a general consensus on the use of indirect
instruments— particularly a short-term interest rate— to ect monetary policy. Indeed, wide-
spread empirical evidence has shown that in those countries, the short-term interest rate is
an ective tool for controlling in‡ation and in‡uencing output growth. By contrast, in de-
veloping countries, the monetary authorities typically operate two main policy instruments to
achieve desirable macroeconomic objectives— a short-term policy interest rate and the required
reserve ratio.
1
However, since early 2000s central banks in those countries have gradually de-
emphasized reserve requirements in favour of a market-based style of monetary policy which
have focussed more on controlling a short-term interest rate. This decision has gained tremen-
dous favour b ecause previous research has shown that the interest rate channel is particularly
important in the transmission mechanism of monetary policy in developing countries.
In small open developing economies, the transmission of monetary policy operates di¤erently
because of weak institutional frameworks and shallow nancial markets (Davoodi et al. (2013)).
2
In addition, those countries typically face macroeconomic challenges related to imperfections
in the nancial sector. For instance, in Caribbean countries, credit market imperfections are
prevalent because the limited competition among banks has led to oligopolistic pricing prac-
tices
3
and market segmentation. Also, in most of those countries, the banking system has high
persistent liquidity which has hindered the ective transmission of monetary policy to key
macroeconomic variables.
4
In light of the presence of structural impediments, the key issue is
whether the monetary authorities in those countries should rely solely (or mainly) on indirect
instruments to conduct monetary policy. Previous research has shown that in countries with
structural excess liquidity and credit market imperfections, the short-term interest rate is lim-
ited in ecting monetary policy. At the same time, there has been contrasting views on the
1
It has been observed that rese rve requirements are generally higher in developing countries, when compared
to developed countries. Therefore, less attention is paid to the use of the required reserve ratio as a policy tool
in developed countries.
2
It should also be noted that in an interconnected world, small open economies are exposed to developments
in the global economy that can hinder the ective transmission of monetary policy.
3
The commercial banks in Barbados, Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago operate under an oligopoly market
structure. See, for instance, Khemraj (2007b) for futher discussions.
4
Several researchers have examined the issue of excess bank liquidity in various Caribbean countries. See
Maynard and Moore (2005), Khemraj (2007a, 2009), Anderson-Reid (2011), Jordan et al. (2012), Primus
(forthcoming) and Primus et al. (2014).
4
ectiveness of the required reserve ratio in transmitting monetary impulses to key macroeco-
nomic variables. Nonetheless, because changes in reserve requirements have a direct in‡uence
on liquidity conditions, central banks in many developing countries have had to resort to this
instrument in recent years. For example, between 2008 and 2010, the central banks of Ja-
maica and Trinidad and Tobago increased the required reserve ratio to absorb excess liquidity
and ect monetary policy. This therefore shows that indirect policy instruments should be
complemented with direct policy to ols in order to achieve desired macroeconomic objectives.
To analyze the ect of monetary policy in the Caribbean, several researchers have held for-
mal discussions on the monetary transmission mechanism in Barbados (see Baksh and Craig-
well (1997) and Moore and Williams (2008)), Jamaica (see Robinson and Robinson (1997)
and Urquhart (2006)), and Trinidad and Tobago (see Watson (1996, 2003), Ramlogan (2007),
Cheong and Boodoo (2008), and International Monetary Fund (2011)). These studies fo cus
on evaluating whether money, credit or the exchange rate is the principal conduit of mone-
tary policy impulses, and the strength of these channels in the transmission process. Although
it is crucial to determine the importance of various channels in transmitting impulses from
the nancial sector to the real sector, the critical issues are which monetary policy tools are
more ective in facilitating such transmission, and how derent policy instruments ect key
macroeconomic variables.
This paper therefore closes the gap in the literature by estimating a macroeconometric model
to evaluate the relative ectiveness of the use of indirect and direct tools of monetary policy
in three of the largest English speaking Caribbean countries— Barbados, Jamaica and Trinidad
and Tobago. In all three countries, the nancial system has been plagued with structural excess
reserves and the nancial market is underdeveloped.
5
See for instance, Ramlogan (2004, 2007),
Holden and Howell (2009), and Birchwood (2011), who also noted that the nancial market in
the Caribbean is underdeveloped. In light of these characteristics, it is important to investigate
how a market-based style of monetary policy would ect key macroeconomic variables in the
short-run. This is an important issue because the monetary authorities in those countries have
shifted their policy stance to rely more on indirect policy tools (so they adjust the short-term
interest rates frequently) to ect monetary policy. Notably, this research represents an essential
contribution as there has been no previous attempt to assess the ects of di¤erent types of
policy instruments in those countries.
To conduct the analysis, a restricted Vector Autoregressive model with Exogenous Variables
(VARX) is used to provide empirical evidence on the relative ects of interest rate and reserve
5
In most Caribbean countries, the nancial sector can be considered developed”if the indicator used is the
ratio of nancial assets to GDP. However, nancial development considers nancial institutions and nancial
markets, the latter of which is underdevelop ed in the Caribbean. In a recent study, the International Monetary
Fund (2015) used a broad-based index to measure nancial sector development. In their study, nancial sector
development was subdivided into nancial institutions and nancial markets. The index showed that in general,
nancial markets are underdeveloped in the Caribbean.
5
requirement policy shocks. In the experiments, the policy interest rate is speci…ed in the form
of a conventional Taylor-type rule, whereas the reserve ratio depends only on its past value.
The model considers the essence of the economies in the Caribbean as it includes variables
that capture the dynamic interaction of the real, banking and external sectors, as well as the
monetary and scal authorities. The extent of the impact of the two policy instruments is
captured through impulse response functions and variance decompositions. The results show
that there is a weak transmission of an increase in the short-term interest rate to output growth
in Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago. Also, in all three countries, a rise in the policy interest
rate is not successful in reducing in‡ation, implying therefore that indirect policy tools may not
be ective for price stability. Moreover, when the required reserve ratio is used as the policy
instrument, a contractionary monetary policy shock helps to alleviate pressure on the exchange
rate in Barbados and Trinidad and Tobago, and is successful in reducing credit demand in
Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section II provides some background informa-
tion on monetary policy in Barbados, Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago. Section III presents
the model and Section IV discusses the econometric results from the impulse response func-
tions and variance decompositions. The nal section provides some concluding remarks and
suggestions.
II. The Caribbean Context
The objectives of monetary policy in the Caribbean are centred on price stability, ensuring
stability of the exchange rate, maintaining an adequate level of foreign exchange reserves and
nancial system stability. The monetary authorities are faced with challenges to achieve these
objectives because the open nature of these countries make them susceptible to external shocks.
6
Also, primarily because of the small size— as well as the distorted nancial systems to a lesser
extent— domestic and external shocks that ect these economies tend to be magni…ed. There-
fore, in formulating monetary policy, the central banks in those economies must take into con-
sideration prevailing and prospective developments in the macro economy, as well as emerging
external sector developments.
The economies of Barbados, Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago have similar nancial struc-
tures. In each country, the commercial banking sector is the largest segment of the nancial
market, as it accounts for the majority of the nancial system assets. This sector is dominated
by a few commercial banks and they operate under an oligopoly market structure. Moreover,
there are some di¤erences in the exchange rate policy pursued by the monetary authorities in
6
These shocks can arise from uctuations in energy prices, spikes in food prices, natural disasters, and capital
account shocks.
6
those countries. Barbados has maintained one of the longest xed exchange rate regimes since
the 1980s (Worrell et al. (2003)). By contrast, Jamaica has a oating exchange rate regime, and
Trinidad and Tobago has a managed oat. Quite often, in these economies, extensive central
bank intervention in foreign exchange markets is needed to smooth volatility and protect the
value of the currency.
There are two key factors of the nancial system that imp ede the transmission of monetary
policy. First, capital markets in each country are at an embryonic stage. Thus, although the
nancial sector of the three countries improved over the last two decades, the nancial market
remains underdeveloped. Second, managing excess bank liquidity in a small open economy with
a fragmented market is a key issue for many central banks in the Caribbean. High persistent
excess liquidity has been a permanent feature of the banking system in Barbados, Jamaica and
Trinidad and Tobago; and over the last decade, the level of excess liquidity has risen to record
levels. In Barbados, Maynard and Moore (2005) noted that the macroeconomic environment,
interest rate policy and money creation by the government are the main factors that contributed
to the build-up of excess reserves. Anderson-Reid (2011) found that in Jamaica an increase
government spending which is facilitated by money creation or borrowing— is associated with
an increase in bank deposits and excess reserves. In the case of Trinidad and Tobago, the
main source of excess liquidity in the economy is the monetization of government deposits
at the Central Bank— which represent tax payments from energy sector companies. Thus, a
signi…cant component of such liquidity has been "involuntary" (see Primus et al. (2014)). In
light of these two issues, the policymakers in those countries have been using a number of
strategies to ect monetary policy.
Several monetary policy tools have been used by the respective central banks. In Barbados,
the monetary policy instruments used are the required reserve ratio, the discount rate, Open
Market Operations (OMOs), moral suasion, and the Central Banks policy rate which is the
minimum deposit rate. In 2013, the Central Bank of Barbados initiated a shift in policy
whereby the Treasury bill rate was used as the key tool to in‡uence interest rates in the
banking sector (see Central Bank of Barbados (2013)). Further, in 2015, the Bank ceased
stipulating a minimum rate of interest on savings deposits at commercial banks. In so doing,
the Central Banks activity in the nancial market, which will in‡uence the Treasury bill rate,
will provide guidance for other interest rates in the banking sector. This therefore shows greater
commitment to indirect policy instruments to conduct monetary policy. To a lesser extent, the
Central Bank of Barbados also stipulates reserve requirements on local deposits, foreign deposits
and government securities, in order to in‡uence economic policy.
In the case of Jamaica, the two main operational tools are OMOs and reserve requirements.
The Bank of Jamaica sets an open market interest rate on OMOs to guide market interest rates.
The reserve ratio includes a cash reserve requirement on local currency liabilities and a liquid
assets ratio, which stipulates the percentage of deposit liabilities to be held as risk-free assets
7
in the form of Government of Jamaica securities of maturities of up to one year (Lattie (2000)).
In addition, for the cash reserve ratio and the liquid assets ratio, a requirement is speci…ed for
foreign currency liabilities.
The Central Bank of Trinidad and Tobago uses a short-term interest rate, OMOs and reserve
requirements to ect monetary policy. OMOs were introduced in 1996 and from 1998 the Bank
started de-emphasizing reserve requirements, while increasing recourse to OMOs (Central Bank
of Trinidad and Tobago (2004)). In 2002, the Central Bank cially changed its stance of
monetary p olicy towards a more market-based monetary policy style as the repo’policy rate
was introduced as the principal instrument to ect monetary policy (Central Bank of Trinidad
and Tobago (2005)). The Central Bank speci…es a primary reserve requirement and a secondary
reserve requirement as a percent of commercial banks prescribed liabilities.
7
Unlike Barbados
and Jamaica, commercial banks in Trinidad and Tobago are not subject to reserve requirements
on government securities and foreign currency liabilities.
The above discussion highlights the fact that both the central banks of Barbados and
Trinidad and Tobago have changed their monetary policy regime to rely more on indirect
policy tools to ect monetary policy. The Bank of Jamaica has not explicitly indicated greater
reliance on the open market rate to ect monetary policy. However, an inspection of the data
shows that the Bank mainly manipulates this rate to indicate its stance. Also, with the excep-
tion of the period 2008-2010, the required reserve ratio in Jamaica has been decreasing since
the late 1990s.
8
Moreover, it has been observed that against the backdrop of high nancial
system liquidity, changes in the short-term interest rate have not been ective in in‡uencing
real variables and bank liquidity; as a result, the central banks had to use other measures.
This therefore underscores the importance of empirically evaluating the ectiveness of the
short-term interest rate (the key indirect policy tool), in comparison to the reserve requirement
ratio (the main direct policy instrument) to determine how each instrument can help to guide
monetary policy in these three small open economies.
III. Econometric Methodology
This section uses the VARX methodology to examine the transmission of a contractionary
monetary policy shock using the short-term interest rate and the required reserve ratio in
Barbados, Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago.
7
Prescribed liabilities represe nt total demand, savings and time deposits, short-term credit instruments with
a maturity up to and including one year and all fund raising instruments maturing within or beyond one year
of the reporting date.
8
For instance, the cash reserve ratio and the liquid asset ratio of commercial banks on local currency deposits
were reduced from 21 percent and 43 percent, respectively in 1998, to 12 percent and 26 percent, respectively
in 2014.
8
A. The Standard VARX Model
According to tkepohl et al. (2006), the structural form of the VARX model can be written
as,
y
t
= A
1
y
t1
+ ::: + A
p
y
tp
+ B
0
x
t
+ ::: + B
q
x
tq
+ C:D
t
+ u
t
; (1)
where y
t
= [y
1t
; :::; y
Kt
]
0
is a vector of K observable endogenous (fully and partially interactive)
variables, x
t
= [x
1t
; :::; x
Mt
]
0
is a vector of M observable exogenous variables, D
t
contains all
deterministic variables, which includes a constant, a linear trend and seasonal dummy vari-
ables, and u
t
= [u
1t
; :::; u
Kt
]
0
is a K-dimensional unobservable zero mean white noise process
with positive de…nite covariance matrix. The A; B and C are parameter matrices of suitable
dimension.
In the VARX framework, restrictions are imp osed in the interactions between variables on
the basis of a priori economic reasoning. Therefore, the VARX system allows for asymmetries
between variables so the number of parameters to be estimated is reduced. This helps to
increase the number of degrees of freedom, as well as improve the ciency of those parameters
to be estimated. Furthermore, the VARX speci…cation allows the modeler to calculate impulse
response functions and variance decompositions associated with innovations on those variables
that are partially endogenous.
B. A VARX for Barbados, Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago
Consider a VARX model which contains three blocks of variables:
a block of fully interactive endogenous variables, the parameters of which are not subject
to restrictions;
a block of partially interactive endogenous variables, the parameters of which are subject
to restrictions; and
a block of strictly exogenous variables.
B.1. Fully Interactive Variables
This block consists of two variables:
The rst variable is the growth rate of real GDP, output_growth
t
, which is used as an
indicator of changes in aggregate demand and economic activity. This variable is measured by
the change in the logarithm of real GDP. Because GDP data are not available on a monthly
9
basis, the Lisman-Sandee pro cedure is used to generate a monthly series from the quarterly
series for all countries. This exercise is carried out using the ECOTRIM software.
9
As the
quarterly data for Trinidad and Tobago is in the form of an index, the data for Barbados and
Jamaica were also converted into an index before the series were interpolated;
The second variable is the in‡ation rate, infl
t
, which is measured as the year-on-year per-
centage change in the logarithm of the Consumer Price Index (CPI), or Retail Price Index
(RPI) for Trinidad and Tobago.
10
This variable is a target of monetary policy.
B.2. Partially Interactive Variables
This block consists of nine variables:
The rst variable is the monetary policy instrument. In the baseline case, a short-term
interest rate, policy_rate
t
, is used to represent the indirect instrument. The policy interest
rate is the minimum savings rate for Barbados, the OMOs 30 day open market interest rate
for Jamaica, and the repo’rate for Trinidad and Tobago. In the macroeconometric model, the
central bank sets a short-term interest rate using a Taylor-type rule in which the policy rate
depends on the ination rate, output growth, and its past value.
11
In the next experiment, the
reserve requirement ratio, rrr
t
, is used to represent the direct instrument of monetary policy.
Thus, this experiment considers a systematic increase in the required reserve rate, which reacts
directly to its past value. This variable is measured using the minimum required reserve ratio on
domestic currency deposits for all countries except Barbados. Over the period of the study the
reserve requirement rate for Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago was adjusted several times. The
required reserve ratio was last changed in 2010 in Jamaica (from 14 percent to 12 percent) and
in 2008 in Trinidad and Tobago (from 15 percent to 17 percent). In the case of Barbados, the
required reserve ratio for both local deposits and government securities which, in combination,
was last changed from 17 percent to 15 percent in 2007— is considered.
12
The second variable is the prime lending rate, plr
t
, which is used to represent commercial
banksloan rate. The prime lending rate interacts with all the variables in the model except
non-fuel world CPI and world oil prices;
9
ECOTRIM is a program that supports temporal disaggregation of high frequency data from low frequency
data.
10
All indices were rebased to 2000.
11
The short-term interest rate rule is referred to as a "Taylor-type" rule because it is the conventional form
of the original Taylor (1993) policy rule.
12
As mentioned in Section II, the Central Bank of Barbados speci…es a reserve ratio for local currency deposits,
foreign currency dep osits and government securities. Over the period of this study, the reserve ratio on local
currency deposits did not change. As a result of this, the statutory ratio on government securities was considered,
in addition to the requirement on local currency deposits.
10
The third variable is the interest rate spread, spread
t
, which is measured as the di¤erence
between commercial banks’prime lending rate and the deposit rate. This variable captures
features of Caribbean countries in which wide interest rate spread re‡ects the oligopoly in‡u-
ence, risk and liquidity in the banking sector. The spread interacts with all the variables in the
model except non-fuel world CPI and world oil prices;
The fourth variable is the real exchange rate, exch_rate
t
. To measure this, the nominal
rate (Bds$/US$; J$/US$; TT$/US$) is de‡ated by U.S. CPI to obtain the real ective rate.
The exchange rate interacts with all the variables in the model except non-fuel world CPI and
world oil prices;
13
The fth variable is the change in private sector credit, cr edit
t
, which is used to capture
the role of credit in funding economic activities. Except for non-fuel world CPI and the world
price of oil, private sector credit also interacts with all the variables in the model;
The sixth variable is the growth rate of government expenditure, govt_exp
t
, which is in-
cluded to capture demand pressures associated with public expenditure. This variable reacts
with output growth, the policy interest rate, the exchange rate, world non-fuel CPI, world oil
prices and its past value. Total expenditure is used because changes in monetary policy can
ect interest payments on domestic debt, and subsequently overall government expenditure;
The seventh variable is the ratio of excess reserves to total reserves, ertr
t
, which is used as
a measure of excess liquidity in the banking system. This variable interacts with all the others
in the model except non-fuel world CPI and the world price of oil;
The eight and ninth variables— non-fuel world CPI, world_CP I
t
, and the world price of
oil, oil_price
t
are included to control for the in‡uence of external factors on the domestic
economy. The non-fuel world CPI accounts for the fact that because the economies are small
and open, in‡ation is strongly in‡uenced by foreign in‡ation; and the annual (year-on-year)
rate of change in the world price of oil captures the ects of changes in energy prices on the
domestic economy. The non-fuel world CPI depends on its past value and the oil price, while
the world price of oil only depends on its past value and is not in‡uenced by any domestic
variables.
The lagged values of all the variables in the Partially Interactive block ects the variables
in the Fully Interactive block.
13
The Real Exchange Rate (RER) is derived using the following formula:
RER=NER(US CPI=CPI for each country); where NER is the Nominal Exchange Rate. Watson (2003)
also used a similar approach in his empirical study to capture the dynamics of the exchange rate channel in the
monetary transmission mechanism of Trinidad and Tobago.
11
B.3. Strictly Exogenous Variables
This block consists of three variables:
A constant term;
A time trend; and
Eleven seasonal dummies are included to capture the ect of seasonality on the variables.
14
B.4. Relationship of Variables
All the variables in the model are important to capture the characteristics of small open
economies and to examine the transmission of monetary policy. The two key instruments
used in the Caribbean to ect monetary policy are a short-term interest rate and the reserve
requirement ratio. Usually, central banks adjust the short-term interest rate taking information
on in‡ation and output growth into account. Therefore, a policy rule, that takes the form of
a conventional Taylor-type rule is used in the framework. Changes in the short-term interest
rate are expected to have a direct impact on the term structure of interest rates in the banking
sector. This ect is expected to be captured through the loan rate and the interest rate spread.
Also, owing to the fact that in the Caribbean commercial banks are the dominant source of
credit to the private sector, this is accounted for through the ratio of private sector credit to
GDP. The reserve requirement ratio is included to capture the ects of a direct policy instru-
ment. It is important to include a measure of excess bank liquidity because the banking system
in the Caribbean has persistently recorded high excess reserves, which impairs the transmission
of monetary policy. It has been observed that quite often reserve requirements are adjusted to
alleviate liquidity pressures.
The real exchange rate is included because in an open economy, monetary policy is trans-
mitted through the exchange rate channel. Therefore, higher domestic interest rates should
result in an increase in demand for the local currency and an in‡ow of capital. It is important
to include a proxy for the scal authority in the model because the ectiveness of monetary
policy can be constrained by the actions of the government— to some extent. For instance, as
previously noted, it has been observed that the governments’…scal operations have contributed
to excess bank liquidity in Barbados, Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago. Also, changes in do-
mestic interest rates and the exchange rate have an impact on government expenditure because
14
The series which displayed seasonality were deseasonalized using the X-12-ARIMA seasonally adjustent
method. An estimation of the model for each country using the deseasonalized series shows no signi…cant
di¤erence in comparison to the results from the mo d el with seasonal dummies. This indicates that the ndings
are robust.
12
they ect interest payments on domestic and external debt. Furthermore, the small and very
open nature of these economies make them susceptible to external shocks, particularly related
to high food prices and the volatility of energy prices. To control for the in‡uence of external
factors on the domestic economy, the non-fuel world CPI and oil prices are included. Domestic
in‡ation, output growth and government expenditure are directly ected by international food
prices and energy price shocks.
Overall, the model includes the dynamic interaction of the main sectors: (1) the real sector,
proxied by growth in real output and the in‡ation rate; (2) the (commercial) banking sector,
which is proxied by a measure of credit, the ratio of excess reserves to total reserves, the prime
lending rate and the interest rate spread; (3) the external sector represented by the real exchange
rate; (4) the monetary authority, whose action is proxied by the short-term interest rate and
the required reserve ratio; and (5) the government’s scal operations, which are captured by
the change in government expenditure.
The sample comprises monthly data from May 2002 to September 2014. Data were con-
strained to this period because the policy rate was implemented in Trinidad and Tobago in
2002. Also, during the period, the central banks relied more on market-based tools to ect
monetary policy. The main data sources are The Central Bank of Barbados, The Central Bank
of Jamaica, The Ministry of Finance of Jamaica, and The Central Bank of Trinidad and Tobago.
To determine the stationarity properties of the individual time series, the Augmented Dickey
Fuller (ADF) and Phillips-Perron (PP) tests were used. In addition, seasonality tests were
conducted on each variable. The results from these tests are summarized in Table 1. The
optimal endogenous lag length is two based on the Akaike Information Criterion and Final
Prediction Error. Thus, using two lags on all endogenous variables, the reduced form of the
VARX model used in this study can be given by,
y
t
= A
1
y
t1
+ A
2
y
t2
+ C:D
t
+ u
t
: (2)
In the baseline case, where the policy_rate
t
is the instrument of monetary policy, the A
matrix is restricted such that:
13
2
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
4
1;1
1;2
1;3
1;4
1;5
1;6
1;7
1;8
1;9
1;10
1;11
2;1
2;2
2;3
2;4
2;5
2;6
2;7
2;8
2;9
2;10
2;11
3;1
3;2
3;3
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
4;1
4;2
4;3
4;4
4;5
4;6
4;7
4;8
4;9
0 0
5;1
5;2
5;3
5;4
5;5
5;6
5;7
5;8
5;9
0 0
6;1
6;2
6;3
6;4
6;5
6;6
6;7
6;8
6;9
0 0
7;1
7;2
7;3
7;4
7;5
7;6
7;7
7;8
7;9
0 0
8;1
0
8;3
0 0
8;6
0
8;8
0
8;10
8;11
9;1
9;2
9;3
9;4
9;5
9;6
9;7
9;8
9;9
0 0
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
10;10
10;11
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
11;11
3
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
5
2
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
6
4
output_g row th
tp
inf l
tp
policy_rate
tp
plr
tp
spread
tp
exch_rate
tp
credit
tp
govt_ exp
tp
ertr
tp
world_CP I
tp
oil _price
tp
3
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
7
5
Notes:
ij
(ij = 1; 2:::), are the co cients on the vector of endogenous variables; p = 1; 2 in
this model; In the second case, the rr r
t
is included in the model as the instrument of monetary
policy and it depends only on its past value. Regarding its order, the rrr
t
is placed after the
policy_rate
t
.
IV. Econometric Results
This section discusses the dynamic impact of a one-standard deviation positive shock to the
policy rate and the required reserve ratio using Lütkepohl, Krätzig and Boreiko’s impulse
response functions and variance decompositions.
15
The solid lines in gures 1, 3, 5, 7, 9, and 11
(see Appendix) show the impulse response functions, while the dotted lines are the associated
95 percent upp er and lower con…dence bands calculated using the bootstrap method.
16
In the
baseline case, the policy interest rate follows a Taylor-type rule where it responds to output
growth, in‡ation and its past value. In the alternative experiment, the required reserve ratio is
included in the model and it responds only to its previous value.
A. Shock to the Policy Rate
In summary, the results show that in Barbados an increase in the short-term interest rate is
not successful in reducing output growth and ination. Also, although a higher policy interest
rate has a direct positive ect on the loan rate and it lowers the interest rate spread, it is not
15
See Lütkepohl and Krätzig (2004) and Lütkepohl et al. (2006).
16
The JMulTi econometrics software was used to estimate the mo d el.
14
successful in reducing credit growth. In Jamaica, a shock to the policy rate leads to a signi…cant
(temporary) fall in both output and excess reserves. The shock, however, has no signicant
ect on the loan rate and the interest rate spread, implying therefore that there can be other
factors that in‡uence how banks determine their interest rates. In the case of Trinidad and
Tobago, an increase in the policy rate has a weak transmission to output growth and it is not
successful in reducing in‡ation. Also, a higher short-term interest rate leads to an exchange
rate appreciation and it has an immediate positive ect on the loan rate. Further discussions
of the results are presented below.
A.1. Barbados
Figure 1 shows the results of a one-standard deviation shock to the p olicy rate. The impulse
response functions show that output growth contracts insigni…cantly at rst, then uctuates
over the period.
17
Initially, ination falls marginally before increasing signi…cantly. This result
is consistent with other studies which have noted that interest rate changes in Barbados have
little or no ect on prices (see for instance, Worrell et al. (2012)). Nonetheless, changes in
the policy rate leads to a direct increase in the prime lending rate. Because the policy rate
is the minimum deposit rate, an increase in this rate reduces the interest rate spread by 0:26
percent. One reason attributed for this is because banks hold excess liquidity, they can be
less inclined to increase loan rates. Further the increase in domestic interest rates leads to an
increase in demand for local currency and causes a statistically signi…cant appreciation of the
real exchange rate in the second month following the shock. This ect is not persistent, and
so the exchange rate returns to its long run equilibrium level after the fth period. Although
the prime lending rate increases, credit falls marginally in the rst period following the shock;
this response however is not signicant. Also, an increase in the policy rate causes government
expenditure to rise signicantly by 0:14 percent, but the ect of the shock quickly dissipates.
This result is consistent with the ndings from Moore and Skeete (2010) which noted that
because of the positive correlation between interest rates on government paper and those set
by the Central Bank of Barbados, a positive monetary policy shock can increase domestic debt
servicing costs. The ratio of excess reserves to total reserves falls signicantly after 5 months
as a higher short-term interest rate causes banks to reduce demand for excess reserves.
The variance decompositions of the domestic variables are presented in Figure 2. The results
show that uctuations in real GDP account for about 87 percent of its own innovations, and
6 percent of world oil prices. Variations in in‡ation contributes between 95 percent and 40
percent of its own innovation, about 20 percent of non-fuel world CPI and 15 percent of world
oil prices. This provides evidence that foreign prices determine domestic in‡ation in small open
economies. Also, in‡ation is ected to a lesser extent by output growth and the policy rate.
17
Similarly, the ndings from a study on Nigeria by Onyukwu and Nwosu (2011) showed that under a market-
based policy, a monetary policy shock leads to persistent volatility in output growth.
15
Changes in the prime lending rate are in‡uenced primarily by both its own shock (45 percent)
and the policy rate (50 percent). The results for the interest rate spread show that its past value
accounts for 40 percent of the uctuations, while the policy rate and the prime lending rate
account for 30 percent and 25 percent of the uctuations, respectively. For the real exchange
rate, about 50 percent of the uctuations can be attributed to its own innovation and ination
accounts for 40 percent. To a lesser extent, variations in the policy rate also ect the real
exchange rate, implying therefore that an increase in domestic interest rates can induce demand
for local currency, thereby in‡uencing capital ows. Furthermore, own innovations contribute
mainly to changes in private sector credit growth, as well as excess liquidity and the policy
rate, to a smaller extent. Government expenditure is determined mainly by its previous value,
85 percent, and the policy rate accounts for about 8 percent of the changes. Finally, variations
in the ratio of excess reserves to total reserves mainly result from its own innovation (95 to 85
percent), and to a lesser extent, government expenditure and the policy rate.
A.2. Jamaica
Figure 5 shows the results of a one-standard deviation shock to the policy rate, which in this
case is the 30 day open market rate. An increase in the policy rate under a Taylor-type rule leads
to a marginal decline in output by 0:03 percent. In‡ation also declines, but this ect is not
signi…cant. Similar to the case of Barbados, the interest rate spread falls because the increase in
the deposit rate is greater than the rise in the prime lending rate. However, in this case, the e¤ect
on the prime lending rate and the interest rate spread is insignicant. Interestingly, following
the shock, the real exchange rate depreciates by 0:05 percent. Although this result is contrary
to a priori expectations, it is possible because in the presence of credit market imperfections,
a positive monetary policy shock can lead to an exchange rate depreciation (see Agénor and
Montiel (2007) and Sen Min (2008) for similar results). It should also be noted that during
the period of this study, there has been a signicant depreciation of the nominal exchange rate
in Jamaica. This can therefore imply that the interest rate must be increased substantially to
induce the demand for local currency. Additionally, on impact of the shock, private sector credit
increases before decreasing, and the fall in private sector credit is signi…cant during the fth to
seventh months, and after the eleventh month. The slow change in credit growth can be due to
the fact that borrowers may be unable to nd alternative sources of funding, and will therefore
continue to borrow at relatively higher interest rates. It has also been noted that in small open
economies, an increase in bank loan rates does not cause loan demand to fall substantially (see
Worrell (1995)). Consistent with the results from Barbados, government expenditure increases
signi…cantly after 4 months. As a higher policy rate causes banks to reduce demand for excess
reserves, the quantity of liquidity falls by 0:07 percent in the second month. This result is
similar to a study by Primus (forthcoming) that found a contractionary monetary policy shock,
resulting from an increase in short-term interest rates, raises the opportunity cost of holding
excess reserves, thereby, lowering the level of excess liquidity in the banking system.
16
Figure 6 illustrates the corresponding variance decompositions of a shock to the policy rate.
The ndings reveal that uctuations in output account for 100 percent of its own innovation
in the rst month and declines gradually over the period to 75 percent. Also, world oil prices
and the policy rate can explain 8 percent and 6 percent, respectively of the variation in output.
For in‡ation, changes are due solely to its past value in the rst period, and this contribution
declines consistently thenceforth. In addition, variation in world oil prices and the ratio of excess
reserves to total reserves contribute to changes in domestic prices. This therefore indicates that
higher excess liquidity can put pressure on prices in Jamaica. Changes in the prime lending rate
are mainly the ects of its own innovations (82 percent), as well as the interest rate spread and
output growth. Given that the policy rate does not contribute substantially to uctuations in
loan rates, this can explain why its ect is insigni…cant in the impulse response function. Also,
the prime lending rate is responsible for approximately 75 percent of the variation in the interest
rate spread. Fluctuations in the exchange rate contribute to 85 percent of its own innovations in
the rst period, but then decline gradually to about 45 percent. Changes in the exchange rate
can also be explained by the policy rate, in‡ation and output growth. Furthermore, the ndings
reveal that growth in private sector credit are due mainly to its own innovation (65 percent),
and to a lesser extent, the policy rate and the ratio of excess reserves to total reserves. For
government expenditure, variations arise mainly because of its past value (86 p ercent), while
changes in the policy rate and world oil prices both account for approximately 4 percent of
the changes. Regarding the ratio of excess reserves to total reserves, about 70 percent of the
uctuations can be explained by its own innovation, as well as the policy rate, world oil prices
and government expenditure, to a smaller extent.
A.3. Trinidad and Tobago
Figure 9 shows the simulations of a one-standard deviation shock to the policy rate. If there
is an increase in the repo’rate, output growth rises before declining signi…cantly during the
tenth and fourteenth months. Thus, there is a slow transmission of changes in the policy rate
to output. Interestingly, following the shock, it is observed that in‡ation rises and remains
signi…cant during the fth and tenth months, before declining gradually. The hump-shaped
pattern is consistent to what is described as the price puzzle ect which is common in VAR
models. See Walsh (2010) for a discussion on the price puzzle ect and Davoodi et al. (2013) for
similar ndings in the East African community. Also, a higher policy rate has an instantaneous
ect on commercial banks prime lending rate, which rises by 0:09 percent following the shock.
Although the prime lending rate increases, the deposit rate does not rise in tandem, causing
the interest rate spread to widen— amid high excess liquidity. As reported in the International
Monetary Fund (2011), deposit rates in Trinidad and Tobago are more resp onsive to cuts in
the repo’policy rate, than increases. Similarly, as shown in Lebedinski (2007) and Agénor and
El Aynaoui (2010), because banks hold excess liquidity, deposit interest rates are more sticky
upward.
17
The in‡ow of capital resulting from a higher policy rate, increases demand for the local
currency, and in turn leads to a signi…cant appreciation of the exchange rate in the second
period. The appreciation dissipates after the sixth p eriod, so the exchange rate returns to its
equilibrium level. This result is similar to a study by Watson (2003) that found an increase
in the Treasury bill rate in Trinidad and Tobago is accompanied by a real exchange rate ap-
preciation. In addition, private sector credit falls in the rst month following the shock, albeit
insigni…cantly. This can be attributed to the fact that because commercial banks are the main
intermediaries, credit demand is not severely ected by changes in the prime lending rate.
Government expenditure increases 2 months after the shock by 0:06 percent as a higher policy
rate raises interest rates on government paper, thereby resulting in increased interest payments
and overall expenditure. Also, changes in the policy rate lead to a decline in the ratio of excess
reserves to total reserves, but this ect is not signicant.
The variance decompositions of the domestic variables are presented in Figure 10. The
results indicate that uctuations in real output are initially due to 100 percent of its own
innovations but declines consistently to 55 percent, whereas the contribution of in‡ation is
more apparent after the seventh month. GDP growth is also a¤ected by changes in the policy
rate and the ratio of excess reserves to total reserves. For in‡ation, uctuations are mainly
because of its own innovations, as well as the policy interest rate and changes in world oil
prices. The results for the prime lending rate show that its own shocks contribute to about 60
percent of the variations overall, and approximately 25 percent is due to changes in the policy
interest rate. To a lesser extent, changes in private sector credit and the ratio of excess reserves
to total reserves ect the prime lending rate. Fluctuations in the interest rate spread account
for approximately 55 percent of its own innovation, 30 percent of the prime lending rate and
12 percent of the policy interest rate. Changes in the exchange rate results from 50 percent
uctuations in its own innovations and 40 percent in in‡ation. Notably, although changes in
the policy rate ect capital ows, its contribution to the movement in the exchange rate is
not substantial (less than 10 percent). Variations in private sector credit reect mostly its own
shocks (about 85 percent) and, to a small extent, changes in the prime lending rate, the policy
interest rate, and output growth. Regarding government expenditure, its own innovations
contribute 85 percent to the changes, while the policy rate is responsible for about 9 percent.
For the ratio of excess reserves to total reserves, approximately 80 percent of the uctuations
depends on its past value, 10 percent is due to in‡ation and the exchange rate is responsible
for 5 percent. It is important to note that although the government’s scal operations is a
key contributory factor to excess liquidity in Trinidad and Tobago (see Primus et al. (2014)),
government expenditure accounts for less than 5 percent of the changes in excess reserves.
18
B. Sho ck to the Reserve Requirement Ratio
Overall, the results show that in the case of Barbados, a higher required reserve ratio is successful
in reducing in‡ation, implying therefore that more direct policy tools can help to contain
in‡ationary pressures in Barbados. In Jamaica, although higher reserve requirements has no
ect on output, it leads to a signicant reduction in in‡ation during the rst period following
the shock. In Trinidad and Tobago, an increase in the required reserve ratio leads to an
immediate signi…cant drop in output growth. The reserve requirement shock is also successful
in reducing both private sector credit and excess reserves. The rest of this section provides
further discussions of the results.
B.1. Barbados
Figure 3 presents the ect of a one-standard deviation shock to the required reserve ratio.
The impulse response functions show that output growth contracts temporarily after 4 months
before rising, but similar to the baseline case of a shock to the policy rate, the ect on output
is not signi…cant. By contrast to the results in Figure 1, higher reserve requirements leads to
a signi…cant fall in in‡ation after 9 months. Also, the prime lending rate increases in the rst
period as the baseline case. However, the ect is insignicant under the shock to the required
reserve ratio. Furthermore, in this case, on impact of the shock the interest rate spread increases
by 0:17 percent because higher reserve requirements causes banks to reduce their deposit rates
and increase their loan rates. This nding is similar to other studies that found a positive shock
to the required reserve ratio acts as a tax on banks so the spread between lending and deposit
rates increases; see for instance Montoro and Moreno (2011), Glocker and Towbin (2012), Tovar
et al. (2012), and Primus (forthcoming). The real exchange rate depreciates signicantly after
7 months. It is important to note that an increase in the required reserve ratio does not have
a signi…cant ect on credit demand and government expenditure. Also, contrary to what is
expected, the ratio of excess reserves to total reserves increases one month after the shock
by 0:09 percent before declining; however, the fall in excess reserves is not signi…cant. In
Barbados, a higher required reserve ratio on local currency deposits is more likely to be caused
by an increase in the security requirement. Under this circumstance, commercial banks are
likely to demand more excess reserves as this can be an opportunity for them to switch excess
idle funds to interest earning securities.
The corresponding variance decompositions of a shock to the required reserve ratio are
shown in Figure 4. An examination reveals that in most cases, the results are similar to the
baseline case of a positive shock to the policy rate (Figure 2). For output growth, world oil
prices account for a marginally smaller share of the uctuations (less than 5 percent). In this
case, variations in in‡ation are attributed to about 2 to 4 percent in the required reserve rate
after the seventh period, whereas the policy rate can explain 2 to 8 percent of in‡ation in the
19
baseline experiment. The contribution of own innovations to the prime lending rate is similar
under both experiments (45 to 52 percent). Further, in this experiment, changes in the interest
rate spread can be explained less by the required reserve ratio (10 percent), as opposed to the
baseline case in which 30 to 38 percent of the variation is attributed to the policy rate. It should
be noted that movements in the exchange rate and private sector credit can be attributed less
to the required reserve ratio, than the policy rate when it is the instrument of monetary
policy. Similarly, the results show that changes in government expenditure depend to a lesser
extent on the policy instrument in this case, as only 3 percent is determined by the required
reserve ratio, compared to 8 percent in Figure 2. In comparison to the shock to the policy rate,
reserve requirements account for a larger share of the movement in the ratio of excess reserves
to total reserves (22 percent), implying therefore that this is an appropriate policy tool that
can in‡uence bank liquidity.
B.2. Jamaica
The impulse response functions of a one-standard deviation shock to the reserve requirement
ratio are presented in Figure 7. The impulse response functions indicate that output falls
following the shock, but unlike the baseline case of a shock to the policy rate (Figure 5), this
ect is insigni…cant. Also, on impact of the shock, ination falls by 0:4 percent, but only
remains signicant in the rst period. Although the ect on in‡ation is short-lived, this result
indicates that reserve requirements can be used as a policy tool for price stability. The interest
rate spread falls by 0:09 percent as a higher required reserve ratio reduces the deposit rate, but
does not increase the lending rate signicantly. Similar to the results in Figure 5, if there is
an increase in the required reserve ratio, the exchange rate depreciates and credit falls from
the second month. Furthermore, government expenditure falls in the rst p eriod and then rises
almost signi…cantly after 4 months. In the second month following the shock, the ratio of excess
reserves to total reserves falls by marginally more than the baseline case, implying therefore
that changes in the reserve requirement ratio have a stronger ect on bank liquidity.
Figure 8 shows the variance decompositions of a shock to the required reserve ratio. An
inspection of the results show that they appear similar to the case of a shock to the p olicy
rate (Figure 6). For output growth, the required reserve ratio can explain less than 0:5 percent
of the uctuations, in comparison to the baseline case in which the policy rate accounts for
approximately 6 percent. Regarding ination, changes in world oil prices can explain a slightly
lower share of its uctuations under a shock to reserve requirements, whereas the contribution
of non-fuel world CPI is about the same under both shocks. In addition, the results show
that more of the variations in the prime lending rate, the interest rate spread, and government
expenditure, can be explained by the required reserve ratio, as compared to the policy interest
rate. However, reserve requirements contribute to a slightly lower share of the variation in
the exchange rate. Similarly, for private sector credit, the required reserve ratio can only
20
explain about 3 percent of its uctuations, as opposed to the baseline case in which the policy
rate accounts for about 10 percent of its changes. Also, when there is an increase in reserve
requirements, government expenditure contributes a slightly lower share to the movements in
the ratio of excess reserves to total reserves in comparison to the baseline case.
B.3. Trinidad and Tobago
Figure 11 presents the results of a one-standard deviation shock to the required reserve ratio.
In this case, in the second month, output falls signi…cantly by 0:05 percent, in contrast to
an increase of 0:07 percent with a shock to the p olicy rate (Figure 9). In‡ation also rises in
this experiment but the ect is insigni…cant. Both the prime lending rate and the interest
rate spread increase in the third month, in comparison to an increase in the rst month in the
baseline case. Further, an increase in the required reserve ratio does not have a signi…cant ect
on the real exchange rate and government expenditure. However, private sector credit contracts
by 0:05 percent in the second month following the shock. Importantly, if there is an increase in
reserve requirements, the ratio of excess reserves to total reserves falls by 0:18 percent in the
second month, contrary to the baseline case where an increase in the policy rate did not lead
to a signicant reduction in the ratio of excess reserves to total reserves.
Figure 12 shows the variance decompositions of a one-standard deviation shock to the reserve
requirement ratio. Overall, the results do not di¤er signi…cantly to the shock to the policy
interest rate. In this case, world oil prices can explain about 1 percent in the real output
growth, unlike the baseline case (Figure 10) in which it accounted for up to 5 percent of the
uctuations. The contribution of the required reserve ratio to changes in output and in‡ation
is far less substantial, in comparison to the policy rate. This nding is contrary to a study
by Ramlogan (2007) that found reserve requirements are important in explaining variations
in output and in‡ation. Also, for the prime lending rate, the interest rate spread, the real
exchange rate and government expenditure, the reserve requirement ratio accounts for less
of the uctuations, as compared to the policy interest rate in the baseline experiment. For
instance, in Figure 12, regarding the interest rate spread, the required reserve ratio contributes
to less than 5 percent of the variations, whereas in the baseline case, the policy rate accounts
for 12 percent of the changes. However, the results for private sector credit and the ratio of
excess reserves to total reserves show that the required reserve ratio can explain more of the
uctuations (about 7 percent and 8 percent, respectively), in comparison to the shock to the
policy rate where it is only responsible for 3 percent and 0:9 percent, respectively of the changes.
21
V. Conclusion and Policy Implications
The purpose of this study was to investigate the relative ectiveness of indirect and direct
monetary policy tools in transmitting monetary impulses in Barbados, Jamaica and Trinidad
and Tobago. A Taylor-type short-term interest rate was used as the indirect p olicy instrument
and the required reserve ratio represented the direct policy tool. To conduct this analysis, the
study estimated a restricted Vector Autoregressive model with Exogenous Variables (VARX),
which incorporated the various sectors of the economy. The model also accounted for the
imperfections in the nancial sector in those countries in particular, excess bank liquidity and
credit market imperfections.
Overall, the results show that there is a weak transmission of changes in the policy interest
rate because of high nancial system liquidity. An analysis of the impulse response functions
reveals that although an increase in the short-term interest rate has an instantaneous ect
on commercial banks loan rates in Barbados and Trinidad and Tobago, this ect does not
translate into a signi…cant fall in private sector credit. Also, higher domestic interest rates
leads to an appreciation of the real exchange rate and an increase in government expenditure
in both countries. By contrast, in Jamaica, a higher policy rate leads to a real exchange rate
depreciation, and a marginal signi…cant increase in government expenditure after 5 months.
The ndings also show that in all three countries, the shock has a muted ect on in‡ation,
which indicates that changes in the short-term interest rate are not su¢ cient to achieve price
stability. Following the shock, output contracts immediately in Jamaica, but it takes 10 months
for a fall in output to be realized in Trinidad and Tobago.
Moreover, a contractionary monetary policy shock via a higher required reserve ratio is
successful in reducing credit demand and it leads to an instantaneous fall in excess reserves in
Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago. Also, in Trinidad and Tobago, higher reserve requirements
can help to reduce output growth faster, and it does not create pressure on the exchange
rate. Furthermore, in Barbados, an increase in the required reserve ratio has no ect on the
government’s interest payments and it leads to a signi…cant depreciation of the exchange rate
after the seventh period.
These results therefore reveal that the central banks of Barbados, Jamaica and Trinidad
and Tobago should use a combination of indirect and direct policy tools to ect monetary
policy. Thus, although the monetary authorities in those countries are employing market-based
measures, indirect policy instruments are not su¢ cient to transmit monetary impulses to key
macroeconomic variables. Furthermore, the monetary authorities should adjust reserve require-
ments on local currency deposits more frequently as this has a direct ect on credit demand
and excess reserves— and this action is not associated with an increase in interest costs. This
result can be particularly imp ortant for Barbados, as that country has not changed the require-
ment on local currency deposits for over a decade. Also, similar to Barbados and Jamaica, the
22
Central Bank of Trinidad and Tobago should consider implementing reserve requirements on
securities. This is because by manipulating the requirement on securities, the Central Bank
can in‡uence other short-term rates, and help to better manage liquidity conditions.
23
References
Agénor, Pierre-Richard and Karim El Aynaoui (2010), "Excess Liquidity, Bank Pricing Rules, and
Monetary Policy," Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 34, pp. 923–933.
Agénor, Pierre-Richard and Peter J. Montiel (2007), "Credit Market Imperfections and the Monetary
Transmission Mechanism Part II: Flexible Exchange Rates," Centre for Growth and Business Cycle
Research Discus sion Paper Series No. 86, University of Manchester.
Anderson-Reid, Karen (2011), "Excess Reserves in Jamaican Commercial Banks: The Implications for
Monetary Policy," Working Paper No. 43663, Munich Personal RePEc Archive (MPRA).
Baksh, Sherman and Roland C. Craigwell (1997), "The Monetary Transmission Mechanism in Small
Open Economies: A Case Study of Barbados," Savings and Development, Vol. 21, pp. 179-193.
Birchwood, Anthony (2011), Implementation of Taylor type Rules in Nascent Money and Capital
Markets Under Managed Exchange Rates”, School of Social Scien ces Theses, Brunel University.
Central Bank of Barbados (2013), "The Central Bank of Barbados Issues a Change
in its Interest Rate Policy," General Press Release: Central Bank of Barbados.
Retrieved at http://www.centralbank.org.bb/news/article/7755/the-central-bank-of-barbados-
issues-a-change-in-its-interest-rate-policy.
Central Bank of Trinidad and Tobago (2004), Rol e and Functions. Central Bank of Trinidad and
Tobago.
(2005), "The Implementation of Monetary Policy in Trinidad and Tobago," Port-of-Spain:
Central Bank of Trinidad and Tobago.
Cheong, Daryl and Earl Boodoo (2008), "The Monetary Transmission Mechanism: A Closer Look at
the Interest Rate Channel in Trinidad and Tobago," Working Paper, Central Bank of Barbados.
Davoodi, Hamid R., Shiv Dixit, and Gabor Pinter (2013), "Monetary Transmission Mechanism in
the East African Community: An Empirical Investigation," Working Paper No. 39, International
Monetary Fund.
Glocker, Christian and Pascal Towbin (2012), "Reserve Requirements for Price and Financial Stability:
When are they ective?," International Journal of Central Banking, Vol. 8, pp. 65-114.
Holden, Paul and Hunt Howell (2009), Enhancing Access to Finance in the Caribbean”, Private
Sector Development Discussion Paper No. 4, Inter-American Development B ank.
International Monetary Fund (2015), World Economic and Financial Surveys, Regional Economic
Outlook, Western Hemisphere: Adjusting Under Pressure”, International Mone tary Fund, October
2015.
(2011), "Trinidad and Tobago: Selected Issues," IMF Country Report No. 74, International
Monetary Fund.
24
Jordan, Alwyn, Sharon Branch, Andrea McQuay, Yvonne Cooper and Latoya Smith (2012), "An
Analysis of Bank Liquidity in The Bahamas (2001-2012)," Working Paper, The Central Bank of
The Bahamas.
Khemraj, Tarron (2007a), "Monetary Policy and Excess Liquidity: The Case of Guyana," Social and
Economic Studies. Vol. 56, pp. 101-127.
(2007b), "What Does Excess Bank Liquidity Say About the Loan Market in Less Developed
Countries?", DESA Working Paper No. 60, United Nations.
(2009), "Excess Liquidity and the Foreign Cu rrency Constraint: The Case of Monetary Man-
agement in Guyana," Applied Economics, Vol. 41, pp. 2073-2084.
Lattie, Claney (2000), "Monetary Policy Management in Jamaica," Pamphlet No. 1, Bank of Jamaica.
Lebedinski, Lara (2007), "Excess Liquidity and Monetary Policy Under Fixed Exchange Rates: A
Theoretical and Empirical Investigation," MSc Dissertation, University of Manchester, United
Kingdom.
Lütkepohl, Helmut, Markus Krätzig (2004): "Applied Time Series Econometrics," Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
Lütkepohl, Helmut, Markus Krätzig and Dmitri Boreiko (2006), "VAR Analysis in JMulTi". Retrieved
at http://www.jmulti.de/download/help/var.pdf.
Maynard, Tracy and Winston Moore (2005), "The Demand for Excess Liquid Assets in Barbados,"
Working Paper, Central Bank of Barbados.
Montoro, Carlos and Ramon Moreno (2011), "The Use of Reserve Requirements as a Policy Instrument
in Latin America," Quarterly Review, Bank for International Settlements.
Moore, Winston and Kevon Skete (2010), "The Implications of Monetary Policy Shocks for Govern-
ment Debt Management in Barbados," Working Paper, Central Bank of Barbados.
Moore, Winston R. and Marlon L. Williams (2008), "Evidence on the Sectoral Monetary Transmission
Process under a Fixed Exchange Rate Regime," International Economic Journal, Vol. 22, pp. 387–
398.
Onyukwu, Onyukwu and Emmanuel Nwosu (2011), "Monetary Policy and Output-in‡ation Volatility
Interaction in Nigeria: Evidence from Bivariate GARCH-M Model," Journal of Economics and
Sustainable Development, Vol. 2, pp. 46-64.
Primus, Keyra (forthcoming), "Excess Reserves, Monetary Policy and Financ ial Volatility," Journal
of Banking and Finance.
Primus, Keyra, Anthony Birchwood and Lester Henry (2014), "The Dynamics of Involuntary Com-
mercial Banks’Rese rves in Trinidad and Tobago," The Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 48, pp.
63-84.
25
Ramlogan, Carlyn (2007), "An ism of Monetary Policy in Small Developing Countries: An Application
to Trinidad and Tobago," The Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 41, pp. 79-91.
, The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy: Evidenc e from the Caribbean”, Journal
of Economic Studies, Vol. 31 pp. 435 447.
Robinson, Wayne and John W. Robinson (1997), "Th e Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy
in the Jamaican Economy," Working Paper, Bank of Jamaica.
Sen M in, Wong (2008), "Monetary Policy Analysis in a Fixed Exchange Rate Economy with Credit
Market Imperfections A Theoretical and Empirical Exploration for Malaysia," PhD Dissertation,
University of Manchester, United Kingdom.
Taylor, John B. (1993), "Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice," Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy, Vol. 39, pp. 195-214.
Tovar, Camilo E., Mercedes Garcia-Escribano and Mercedes V. Martin (2012), "Credit Growth and the
ectiveness of Reserve Requirements and Other Macroprudential Ins truments in Latin America,"
Working Paper No. 142, International M onetary Fund.
Urquhart Mikhail-Ann F. (2006), "The Reaction of Bank Lending to Monetary Policy: The Jamaican
Case," Working Paper, Bank of Jamaica.
Walsh, Carl E. (2010), Monetary Theory and Policy, Third edition, The MIT Press Cambridge, Massa-
chusetts.
Watson, Patrick Kent (1996), "The Monetary Transmission Process in a Small Open Economy: The
Case of Trinidad and Tobago," Working Paper, Caribbean Centre for Monetary Studies.
(2003), "Evaluating Monetary Policy Measures in a Small Primary-Exporting Economy: The
Case of Trinidad and Tobago," Social and Ec onomic Studies, Vol. 52, pp. 143-166.
Worrell, DeLisle (1995) "Monetary Policy in Small Open Economies," Working Paper, Central Bank
of Barbados.
Worrell, DeLisle, Harold Codrington, Roland Craigwell and Kevin Grenidge (2003) "Economic Re-
silience with an Exchange Rate Peg: The Barbados E xperience, 1985-2000," Working Paper No.
168, International Monetary Fund.
Worrell, DeLisle, Michelle Doyle-Lowe, Anton Belgrave, Darrin Downes and Kester Guy (2012), "Cen-
tral Bank Intervention and Interest Rate Policy in Barbados," Working Paper, Central Bank of
Barbados.
26
Table 1. Unit Root and Seasonality Tests
Barbados
Trinidad and Tobago
Variable
Order of
Integration
Seasonal
Dummies
Trend
Order of
Integration
Seasonal
Dummies
Trend
Order of
Integration
Seasonal
Dummies
Trend
output_growth
I(1)
I(1)
I(0)

infl
I(0)
I(0)
I(0)
policy_rate
I(1)
I(1)
I(1)
rrr
I(0)
I(1)
d7
I(1)
plr
I(1)
d10
I(1)
I(1)
spread
I(0)
I(0)

I(1)
d11
exch_rate
I(1)
d1, d3, d8
I(0)

I(1)
d3
credit
I(1)
I(1)
I(1)
govt_exp
I(0)
I(0)

I(0)
ertr
I(1)
I(0)

I(0)
d9
world_CPI
I(0)
I(0)
I(0)
oil_price
I(0)
I(0)
I(0)
27
Barbados
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Policy Interest Rate
Figure 1. Impulse Response Functions
28
Barbados
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Policy Interest Rate
Figure 2. Variance Decompositions
29
Barbados
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio
Figure 3. Impulse Response Functions
30
Barbados
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio
Figure 4. Variance Decompositions
31
Jamaica
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Policy Interest Rate
Figure 5. Impulse Response Functions
32
Jamaica
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Policy Interest Rate
Figure 6. Variance Decompositions
33
Jamaica
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio
Figure 7. Impulse Response Functions
34
Jamaica
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio
Figure 8. Variance Decompositions
35
Trinidad and Tobago
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Policy Interest Rate
Figure 9. Impulse Response Functions
36
Trinidad and Tobago
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Policy Interest Rate
Figure 10. Variance Decompositions
37
Trinidad and Tobago
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio
Figure 11. Impulse Response Functions
38
Trinidad and Tobago
One-Standard Deviation Shock to the Reserve Requirement Ratio
Figure 12. Variance Decompositions