\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 1 14-JUN-19 7:19
PLANNED OBSOLESCENCE AND CONSUMER
PROTECTION: THE UNREGULATED
EXTENDED WARRANTY AND SERVICE
CONTRACT INDUSTRY
Larry A. DiMatteo* & Stefan Wrbka**
This Article analyzes the billion-dollar market, mostly unregulated,
for Extended Warranties and Service Contracts (EWSCs). EWSCs are
ubiquitous in the modern marketplace, offered at every automobile deal-
ership, electronics and appliance store either by a salesperson or the
cashier. Incredibly, there is little legal scholarship in this important area
where manufacturer-sellers often overreach by preying on consumer vul-
nerabilities. It will be argued that most sales of EWSCs result in price
gouging due to informational asymmetry and behavioral manipulation.
This Article looks at two core concepts that are inexorably intercon-
nected—one in the legal world and the other in the world of business and
technology. The former relates to the regulation of EWSCs. The latter
addresses the idea of “planned obsolescence” in which manufacturers
determine the life or durability of their products. Products are engi-
neered to fail such that they will need to be repaired or replaced for the
purpose of generating future revenues for manufacturers and sellers.
This inside information also allows manufacturers and third-party insur-
ers to predict the low costs and risks of selling EWSCs. This Article re-
views the marketplace and the practices of the high-pressure selling of
EWSCs for products ranging from automobiles to electronics and less
expensive goods. It then provides a comparative analysis of the state of
the law in the United States, the European Union, and individual Euro-
pean countries. This comparative metric is important due to the fact that
different countries have moved faster to regulate this industry (the
United States is not one of them). It concludes that sellers of EWSCs
often overreach and that a stronger regulatory framework is needed.
Recommendations are offered on how best to frame new rules to ensure a
fair and efficient market in the sale of consumer goods.
* Huber Hurst Professor of Contract Law, University of Florida; J.D., Cornell Law
School; LL.M., Harvard University; Ph.D., Monash University.
** Unit Head and Academic Coordinator, Business Law, University of Applied Sciences
for Management and Communication, Vienna; Mag. iur., University of Vienna; LL.M., Kyu-
shu University; Ph.D., University of Vienna.
483
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 2 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
R
484
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
I
NTRODUCTION
................................................. 485
I.
EWSC
S AND
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE
.................. 490
A. EWSCs ............................................ 490
B. Planned Obsolescence .............................. 492
II.
M
ARKETPLACE AND
R
EGULATORY
L
ANDSCAPES OF
EWSC
SINTHE
U
NITED
S
TATES
,
THE
EU,
AND
E
UROPEAN
M
EMBER
S
TATES
....................................... 495
A. United States ...................................... 495
1. Relevance of EWSCs in the U.S. ............... 495
2. Regulatory Landscape of EWSCs in the U.S. .... 499
a. Federal Warranty Law...................... 499
b. State Law: Common Law of Contracts and
Uniform Commercial Code (UCC) .......... 500
c. State Regulation: New York Insurance Law . 502
d. Restatement of Consumer Contract Law ..... 505
e. Lemon Laws ............................... 507
B. EU and Member States ............................. 508
1. Relevance of EWSCs in the EU ................ 509
2. Regulatory Landscape of EWSCs in the EU ..... 510
C. Regulatory Insufficiencies Related to EWSCs in the
EU and EU Member States ......................... 518
III.
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
EWSC
S
.................. 523
A. United States ...................................... 524
1. Contract Law’s Response to Planned
Obsolescence .................................. 525
2. Regulatory and Judicial Responses .............. 526
B. The EU and Member States ......................... 528
1. Legal Development at the EU level ............. 529
2. Situation in Selected Member States ............ 531
IV.
R
ECOMMENDATIONS FOR
R
EGULATORY
R
EFORM
.......... 534
A. Initial Considerations .............................. 535
B. Generalized Versus Specialized Rules ............... 537
C. Comprehensive and Specialized Laws are Needed .... 538
D. Improving Informed Decision-Making ............... 539
E. Refined Warranty Regime ........................... 541
F. Enhanced Support and Enforcement ................. 543
C
ONCLUSION
................................................... 544
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 3 14-JUN-19 7:19
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
485
I
NTRODUCTION
There are always regulatory gaps in complex, modern economies.
One of those gaps is the aggressive selling of the mostly worthless ex-
tended warranty (guarantee) or service contract (EWSC).
1
EWSCs are
sold across different industries including in the automobile and electronic
products industries. The selling of EWSCs is a multi-billion-dollar indus-
try in which eight out of ten dollars of an EWSC’s price is profit!
2
The
following “Ode” provides a framework for the examination of this regu-
latory gap:
Ode to the Modern Marketplace
(The Product)
There once were industries, which touted the new technologies that
converted Grandma’s old refrigerator (still working after sixty years) into
a multi-dimensional refrigerator, entertainment system, and calorie-
counting marvel of a product. But not all is well in the land of appli-
ances, electronics, automobiles, and so forth. This increased use of tech-
nology, along with the use of less durable materials, act as a poison that
profoundly impacts the lifespan of these products. If this is so, then these
super-gadgets are not much of a sign of progress!
(The Consumer)
If the above observation is so, shouldn’t purchasers be more fully
informed of the shorter product lifespans due to technology or the quality
of materials used in producing them? Maybe the manufacturer should be
required to put a notice on its product that reads something like: “This
high-priced product does a lot of ‘cool’ things, but it will cost you a lot
more to repair; but, no worries, those repairs will be needed for a shorter
period of time before you will need a replacement!”
(The Flimflam)
To ease your concerns, the retailer is willing to provide ‘peace of
mind’ by selling to the unsuspecting consumer an extended warranty-
1
The European name for warranty is guarantee; the words will be used interchangeably
throughout this Article. See, e.g., Consumers, Health, Agric. and Food Exec. Agency (Chafea),
Consumer Market Study on the Functioning of Legal and Commercial Guarantees for Con-
sumers in the EU: Final Report, at 18 (Dec. 2015), https://publications.europa.eu/en/publica-
tion-detail/-/publication/146e59de-02d3-11e6-b713-01aa75ed71a1/language-en [hereinafter
Market Study].
2
See The SAFE Guys: As with Manufacturer’s Product Warranties, the Extended War-
ranty Industry is Huge Yet Easy to Take for Granted. Two Industry Experts Explain Why They
Left the Comfort of the Insurance Business to Open Their Own Extended Warranty Con-
sultancy., Warranty Week (Sept. 28, 2004), https://www.warrantyweek.com/archive/
ww20040928.html [hereinafter The SAFE Guys].
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 4 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
486
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
service contract (EWSC) at an obscene price based on the ‘planned obso-
lescence’ of the product (knowledge possessed by the manufacturer or
third-party insurer) ensuring that the retailer-manufacturer-insurer will
pay minimal repair costs and thereby generate exorbitant profits. Or,
more poetically, the manufacturer confidently suggests that they “stand
behind the quality of their products”; that is, they build their products to
last but just a bit past the duration of the EWSC!
Isn’t it implausible to believe today’s products and their lifespans are
generally shorter than bygone eras’, and that the rise of the multi-billion-
dollar EWSC industry is merely a manipulation of this trend at the indus-
try-level? Or is it? Ought we to do something about it? These questions
are the focus of this Article.
Recently, one of the authors experienced the “thrill” of purchasing a
new car. This experience provides a prototypical example of a con-
sumer’s introduction to the EWSC industry. The true-life scenario, repli-
cated thousands of times a day, involved the hard sell by the retailer of
an EWSC—also known as a “paid-for commercial guarantee”
3
—on be-
half of itself, a manufacturer, or a non-producer third-party insurer (third-
party insurer), no doubt including a handsome fee for the auto dealership
as a result of reverse competition.
4
The transaction involved the cash
purchase of a new mid-sized car. Even though it was a cash purchase, the
customer was told that he must first wait to talk to the finance manager.
Since there was no financing or leasing involved, this could and did
mean that the manager was in charge of the hard sell of an EWSC.
The sales pitch involved a two-pronged attack meant to manipulate
the purchaser into seeing the “value” of a paid-for EWSC.
5
First, the
manager “puffed”
6
that he normally wouldn’t buy such an EWSC, but
3
Market Study, supra note 1. For alternative terminology see infra Section I.A.
4
Reverse competition is most often a three-part deal where the buyer may or may not
know about the commission, kickback, or finders’ fee. There are always three parties to make
this work; in the case of EWSC: insurer-provider, retail seller, and the purchaser. See The
SAFE Guys, supra note 2. As will be seen, it is often a four-party deal: insurer-provider, retail
seller, administrator, and the purchaser.
5
The term paid-for or pre-paid warranty is used to distinguish it from the ordinary
express or implied warranty that is included in the purchase price. See Market Study, supra
note 1, tbl.1, at 18.
6
Puffery refers to an exaggeration, whether an outright opinion or an opinion that acts
as a pseudo-fact, as that no reasonable person would take as factual but serves as a technique
of persuasion. See Phx. Payment Sol., Inc. v. Towner, No. CV-08-651-PHX-DGC, 2009 U.S.
Dist. LEXIS 91978, at *16 (D. Ariz. Oct. 2, 2009) (quoting Zack v. Allied Waste Indus., Inc.,
No. CIV04-1640-PHX-MHM, 2005 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 35323, at *9 (D. Ariz. Dec. 15. 2005)).
The characterization of statements as puffery is a defense to a fraud or warranty claim. The
argument is that no reasonable person would have taken the seller or advertiser’s words as
statements of fact. Id. (“[T]he difference between a statement of fact and mere puffery rests in
the specificity or generality of the claim.” (quoting Newcal Indus., Inc. v. IKON Office Sol.,
513 F.3d 1038, 1053 (9th Cir. 2008))).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 5 14-JUN-19 7:19
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
487
that with the increased use of computer applications and other new tech-
nologies in the manufacture of new cars, such warranties are almost a
necessity. He followed this pitch with the statement that he had pur-
chased such a warranty for his new car. Second, following the sales
pitch, the customer was “forced” to view a four-minute video extolling
the benefits and peace of mind that such paid-for EWSCs provide.
Given the above sales tactics, the customer is left feeling that there
is a high probability that a major repair or defect is likely to occur during
the EWSC period of coverage (but planned obsolescence upon which
EWSCs are based show that this will not be the case). Further, the cus-
tomer is made to believe that the rational, intelligent purchaser would
buy such a service contract. Finally, there is the moral suasion affected
by the manager’s passionate appeal to the customer that he has the cus-
tomer’s best interests at heart.
Unfortunately, some retailers go well beyond mere hard selling or
mere persuasion. Unscrupulous dealers have falsely claimed that an
EWSC is required in order to obtain bank financing; others simply add
the cost of the EWSC into the loan agreement without consent.
7
The
EWSC also may have numerous anti-purchaser provisions that limit
claims that a reasonable purchaser would expect to be covered given the
high price charged for the EWSC—some EWSCs have deductibles on a
repair basis or a per-visit basis (even if it is for the same repair); others
have limits or absolute exclusions for some types of repairs (such as re-
pairs due to “normal wear and tear”). Still others may limit the geo-
graphic scope of where the repairs can be made (thus, you may not be
close to an authorized or designated repair shop if you move) or place
caps on towing charges or rental car expenses. Some insurers add a de-
preciation factor in order to make only a partial payment for covered
parts and repair.
8
Thus, not only are EWSCs overpriced, they often pro-
vide less coverage than expected. In the end, the U.S. Federal Trade
7
See U.S. F
ED
. T
RADE
C
OMM
N
(FTC), A
UTO
S
ERVICE
C
ONTRACTS AND
W
ARRANTIES
(Aug. 2012), https://www.consumer.ftc.gov/articles/0054-auto-service-contracts-and-warran
ties. The U.S. Federal Trade Commission warns that:
If the dealer tells you that you have to buy a service contract to qualify for financing,
contact the lender to find out if this is true. Some people have had trouble canceling
their service contract after learning that the lender didn’t require one.
Also beware of unscrupulous dealers who may try to include an auto service
contract in your loan without your consent. If you see a charge for a service contract
that you didn’t agree to, tell the dealer to take it out before you sign the loan
agreement.
. . . .
. . . [M]ake sure the dealer forwards your payment and you get written confir-
mation. Some people discovered too late that the dealer failed to forward their pay-
ment, leaving them with no coverage months after they signed a contract.
Id.
8
The Federal Trade Commission notes that:
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 6 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
488
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
Commission and other federal agencies leave consumers to fend for
themselves without any legal protections relating to the sale of EWSCs.
Normally, this particular purchaser would have stopped the manager
before he got started, but it had been a while since he had purchased a
new car and wanted to witness the “life and death” faux sincerity and
pressure placed on customers to purchase the EWSC. Little did the man-
ager know that the customer already calculated that the cost of the
EWSC, about $1,800 or 10% of the cost of the automobile, was outra-
geous and that its key importance was as a major revenue-generating
enterprise and not consumer protection.
9
EWSCs are not industry-specific; in fact, the high-pressure sales
tactics to buy service contracts are found in many other areas, such as in
the electronics industry, even when the actual product is simple and low
cost, which makes the purchase of an EWSC nonsensical.
10
This all too common scenario highlights consumer abuse in the area
of paid-for EWSCs. There are numerous red flags—high-pressure sale
tactics, informational asymmetry, standard-form contracting—that sug-
gest additional regulation of the EWSC industry is needed. The high de-
gree of pressure placed by sellers of such contracts suggests that these
contracts are not meant to minimize the risks to the customer, but are
sold for the benefit of the seller. The revenues generated from the sale of
such contracts rest on probability estimates of the likelihood of EWSC
claims being made during the extended period and the average amount of
the costs of such claims. The ultimate insurer, generally the manufacturer
In addition, you may need to pay a deductible. Find out if the deductible is charged
on a per visit or per repair basis. This can make a big difference . . . .
Service contracts often limit how much they will pay for towing or related
rental car expenses—meaning you have to cover the remaining cost. There also may
be transfer or cancellation fees if you sell your car or end the contract early.
. . . [Some service contracts have] absolute exclusions that deny coverage for
any reason. For example: If a covered part is damaged by a non-covered part, the
claim may be denied. Or if the contract specifies that only “mechanical breakdowns”
will be covered, problems caused by “normal wear and tear” may be excluded . . . .
[Also, y]ou may not have full protection even for parts that are covered in the
contract. Some companies use a “depreciation factor” in calculating coverage: the
company may pay only partial repair or replacement costs based on your car’s
mileage.
Id.
9
For further comments on the relevance of EWSCs, see the U.S. and EU data supra
Parts II.A.1, II.B.1. It would be more prudent and rational for the consumer to invest the
$1,800 for the eight years that the EWSC covers, because planned obsolescence shows that
there will be a large surplus after paying for the handful of minor repairs needed for the eight
years of the automobile’s life. See The SAFE Guys, supra note 2.
10
Another example, involving one of the authors, involved the purchase of a paper
shredder. The shredder, originally priced, at $129 was on sale for $69. At the cash register, the
store’s employee began to enter the $29 cost of the service contract! It was only after the
author objected that the person removed the add-on costs of the paid-for EWSC.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 7 14-JUN-19 7:19
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
489
or a third-party insurer, possesses the information needed to do the calcu-
lation while the buyer is ignorant as to the likelihood that she will have to
make substantial claims in the future. As noted previously, this calcula-
tion is based on the concept of “planned obsolescence.”
11
As will be
discussed, manufacturers are not making products meant to last, but
rather made just to last until the expiration of the EWSC, forcing con-
sumers to buy new products when the ones originally purchased stop
working.
12
This Article asks: what if products, even so-called high-quality
ones, are being produced with shorter lifespans, not because of techno-
logical advancements,
13
but because of planned obsolescence? Should
the law intervene, if not with higher quality standards, then in the area of
warranty law?
Part I starts with a basic outline of the two core concepts of EWSCs
and planned obsolescence. The definitions of these two core concepts
will provide the framework for understanding the subsequent analysis.
Part II discusses the significance of the EWSC industry in the United
States and the European Union (EU) and outlines the underlying regula-
tory frameworks. It also highlights some of the most striking regulatory
insufficiencies related to paid-for EWSCs in the EU and EU Member
States. Relevant aspects of the planned obsolescence phenomenon will
11
Planned Obsolescence has been defined as the use of “strategies and techniques of
premature product aging applied by producers and sellers for the purpose of making end users
replace old products with new ones faster than they ordinarily would by shortening the time of
their use.” Stefan Wrbka, Warranty Law in Cases of Planned Obsolescence—The Austrian
Situation, 6 EuCML 67, 67 (2017).
12
Things don’t seem to work or last like they used to. The new state-of-the-art, high-
tech, high-priced substitutes seem to require constant attention (high maintenance and repair
costs) in order to squeeze ten years or so of life out of them. One of the authors has described
it as follows:
[D]eclining lifetimes in a historical context could be a further indicator of a non-
acceptable, i.e. warranty-relevant[,] defect constituting lifetime. If, for example, a
washing machine of a relevant product series shows a shorter lifetime than compara-
ble products ten years ago, then one could see this as an additional argument for a
possible warranty-relevant defect. One would have to consider, in particular,
whether there is any justified reason that could explain a decline and further consider
that technical advancement should rather—at least—maintain the lengths of product
lifetimes over time.
Id. at 69.
13
One would hope new technologies that allow a product, such as a refrigerator to do
more things does not act as a poison that profoundly impacts the lifespan of the product. If so,
that would not be much of an improvement. If it is the case that technology shortens product
lifespans, shouldn’t the purchaser be given more information such as: “This high priced prod-
uct does a lot of ‘cool’ things, but it will cost you more to repair it, but no worries those repairs
will be needed for a shorter period of time before you will need a replacement! And, in addi-
tion, we are willing to sell an extended warranty-service contract at an obscene price based on
the planned obsolescence of the product so that we can minimize our repair costs and insure
ourselves an exorbitant profit”—or, more poetically—”We stand behind the quality of our
product, that is, we build our products to last just a bit past the EWSC!”
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 8 14-JUN-19 7:19
490
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
be further discussed in Part III (in particular from a regulatory perspec-
tive). The Article will conclude with suggestions for further steps to be
taken to better protect purchasers of EWSCs.
I. EWSC
S AND
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE
When taking a closer look, both terms—EWSC and planned obso-
lescence—turn out to be remarkably ambiguous. Depending on the con-
crete circumstances, the concepts can be used in a number of ways.
14
To
facilitate the understanding of our analysis, it makes sense to briefly out-
line their meaning in the context of this Article.
A. EWSCs
When buyers purchase goods, they usually expect to get what they
pay for or—framed more objectively—what they reasonably may expect
to receive. The equivalence between the amount of money paid and the
qualitative or durability value of the good received could be impaired if
the good does not conform to the quality owed. To remedy non-conform-
ity issues, safeguards are sometimes found either in the form of legal and
14
For examples of EWSC definitions, see V. Padmanabhan & Ram C. Rao, Warranty
Policy and Extended Service Contracts: Theory and an Application to Automobiles, 12 M
AR-
KETING
S
CI
. 230, 230 (1993); Keyvan Samini, Third Party Extended Warranties and Service
Contracts: Drawing the Line Between Insurance and Warranty Agreements, 54 O
HIO
S
T
. L.J.
537, 541 (1993); Joseph S. Cheng & Stephen J. Bruce, A Pricing Model for New Vehicle
Extended Warranties, C
ASUALTY
A
CTUARIAL
S
OC
Y
F. 1, 12 (1993); L. Nicholas Weltmann,
Jr. & David Muhonen, Extended Warranty Ratemaking, C
ASUALTY
A
CTUARIAL
S
OC
Y
F. 187,
190–91 (2001); Kenneth J. Rojc & Gregory Eidukas, New Frontiers in Automotive Sale and
Finance Products, 60 B
US
. L
AW
. 663, 668 (2005); Ruth N. Bolton, Katherine N. Lemon &
Peter C. Verhoef, Expanding Business-to-Business Customer Relationships: Modeling the
Customer’s Upgrade Decision, 72 J. M
ARKETING
46, 46 (2008); Michelle Bertolini & Sharon
S. Lassar, Service-Warranty Companies—The Hybrid of the Insurance Industry, 38 T
AX
A
D-
VISER
402, 402 (2007); Lynden Griggs, Extended Warranties and Internet Transactions, C
OM-
PETITION
& C
ONSUMER
L.J. LEXIS, Nov. 2008, at *5; Lynden Griggs, Providing an Extended
Warranty with an Online Transaction: The Model That Will Improve Consumer Confidence,
13 J. I
NTERNET
L. 16, 16–17 (2009); Tao Chen, Ajay Kalra & Baohong Sun, Why Do Consum-
ers Buy Extended Service Contracts?, 36 J. C
ONSUMER
R
ES
. 611, 611 (2009); Peng Tong,
Zixian Liu, Feng Men & Lisi Cao, Designing and Pricing of Two-Dimensional Extended War-
ranty Contracts Based on Usage Rate, 52 I
NT
L
J. P
RODUCTION
R
ES
. 6362, 6362 (2014); Nat
Pope, Chiharu Ishida, Peter Kaufman & Frederick W. Langrehr, Extended Warranties in the
U.S. Marketplace: A Strategy for Effective Regulation, 33 J. I
NS
. R
EG
. 67, 69 (2014); Pranav
Jindal, Risk Preferences and Demand Drivers of Extended Warranties, 34 M
ARKETING
S
CI
. 39,
39 (2015); Yukun Wang, Zixian Liu & Yiliu Liu, Optimal Preventive Maintenance Strategy
for Repairable Items Under Two-Dimensional Warranty, 142 R
ELIABILITY
E
NGINEERING
&
S
YS
. S
AFETY
326, 326 (2015); Duo Yang, Zhen He & Shuguang He, Warranty Claims Fore-
casting Based on a General Imperfect Repair Model Considering Usage Rate, 145 R
ELIABIL-
ITY
E
NGINEERING
& S
YS
. S
AFETY
147, 147 (2015); Zhi-Sheng Ye & D.N. Pra Murthy,
Warranty Menu Design for a Two-Dimensional Warranty, 155 R
ELIABILITY
E
NGINEERING
&
S
YS
. S
AFETY
21, 21 (2016).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 9 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
491
statutory obligations placed on sellers or via party autonomy, as agreed
on by the parties to the sales contract (warranty).
In the literature, various terms are used to refer to these two regula-
tory scenarios. A 2015 study
15
commissioned by the European Commis-
sion (2015 Market Study) offers a good overview of the linguistically
and conceptually multilayered guarantee frameworks. It distinguishes be-
tween legal guarantees and commercial guarantees, subdivides commer-
cial guarantees into “integral [no-cost] commercial guarantees” and
“paid-for commercial guarantees” (a synonym for EWSCs),
16
and aims
to unify the terms used in the literature under these three types of
guarantees:
1. Legal guarantees, also known as “statutory
guarantees”;
2. Integral commercial guarantees, also known as
“guarantees”, “manufacturer’s guarantees”, “warran-
ties”; and
3. Paid-for commercial guarantees, also known as “ex-
tended warranties”, “service contracts”, “care plans”,
“service plans”, “extended service contracts”.
17
Because of the significant conceptual differences, this Article will distin-
guish between and focus on two of these three forms of guarantees: legal
guarantees on the one hand and paid-for EWSCs (paid-for commercial
guarantees) on the other. Legal guarantees, prescribed by law, come at
no extra cost to the purchaser of the respective good. EWSCs, on the
other hand, result from party agreements offered at an additional price,
are a collateral agreement to the sale contract, and form a business of
their own.
18
Paid-for EWSCs are provided by a number of entities. They are
commonly offered by the manufacturer or seller of the product, but are
sometimes sold by third-party insurers.
19
Third-party insurers often mar-
ket their EWSCs after the sale of the product, often through mail adver-
tisements or notices at the time the product warranty is due to expire.
These types of expiration notices or advertisements are especially manip-
ulative since they prey on owner fears that they are no longer covered.
15
Market Study, supra note 1.
16
Id. tbl.1, at 18.
17
Id.
18
Again, ‘integral commercial guarantees’ are distinguishable from EWSCs in that in
the first case the guarantee is offered at no additional cost even though it is beyond the war-
ranty period required by law, while the latter is a paid-for extended warranty. The first type is
likely given for branding and signaling purposes to show that the seller is selling a quality
product.
19
See The SAFE Guys, supra note 2. Third-party insurers are commonly insurance
companies.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 10 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
492
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
EWSCs offer longer guarantee periods beyond statutory or integral
warranties, and thereby create additional obligations and liabilities for
the seller and other parties involved in the EWSC scheme.
20
These addi-
tional liabilities arise from extending the time of the guarantee period,
and also from expanding the scope of guarantee protections for addi-
tional services and insurance coverage, such as compensation for acci-
dental damage loss. Unless indicated otherwise, the term EWSC in the
present context refers to paid-for EWSCs of any kind, including those
that extend beyond the expiration of other types of guarantees to those
that provide different types of coverage, such as additional loss
coverage.
21
B. Planned Obsolescence
The idea of planned obsolescence has been around for a while,
traceable to at least the Great Depression.
22
For example, the charge has
been made that appliances today are not made to last, but are instead
made to fail in a shorter period of time than the state of the art allows
without any prohibitive increase in production costs.
23
One of the first
reported (and confirmed) cases of planned obsolescence dates back to the
1920s, when a group of manufacturers—commonly known as the “Phoe-
20
See Market Study, supra note 1, tbl.1, at 18. For example, under the EU framework for
legal guarantees, the directly liable party would (only) be the seller of a product. EWSCs could
go beyond and would in many cases introduce a manufacturer liability and occasionally (also
or alternatively) a third-party insurer liability.
21
One must, however, not neglect the fact that the term “commercial guarantees” is
occasionally used in a narrower way. One of the most prominent examples is the Consumer
Rights Directive (CRD) outlined further below. Article 2(14) of the CRD defines CRD-rele-
vant EWSCs as:
Any undertaking by the trader or a producer (the guarantor) to the consumer, in
addition to his legal obligation relating to the guarantee of conformity, to reimburse
the price paid or to replace, repair or service goods in any way if they do not meet
the specifications or any other requirements not related to conformity set out in the
guarantee statement or in the relevant advertising available at the time of, or before
the conclusion of the contract.
Directive 2011/83/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 25 October 2011 on
Consumer Rights, Amending Council Directive 93/13/EEC and Directive 1999/44/EC of the
European Parliament and of the Council and repealing Council Directive 85/577/EEC and
Directive 97/7/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council, 2011 O.J. (L 304) 64, 73
[hereinafter CRD]. This statement represents a remarkably narrow understanding because it
excludes third-party guarantors (other than producers) from the application of the CRD
regime.
22
See B
ERNARD
L
ONDON
, E
NDING THE
D
EPRESSION THROUGH
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE
1 (1932); G
ILES
S
LADE
, M
ADE TO
B
REAK
: T
ECHNOLOGY AND
O
BSOLESCENCE IN
A
MERICA
5
(2006).
23
See Planned Obsolescence, T
HE
E
CONOMIST
, Mar. 23, 2009, https://www.econo
mist.com/news/2009/03/23/planned-obsolescence; S
LADE
, supra note 22.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 11 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
493
bus cartel”
24
or “Phoebus agreement”
25
—agreed on limiting the lifetime
of light bulbs to a maximum of 1,000 hours of operation.
26
The revela-
tion of the Phoebus cartel initiated a debate on the interrelationship be-
tween increasing profits, producing eco-friendly and sustainable goods,
and consumers’ interests in being able to buy goods that will last as long
as technologically possible.
27
Since the 1970s, there have been an increasing number of economic
studies aimed at defining the most profitable strategies to balance techno-
logical innovation with businesses’ rights to maximize profits (such as
calculating the likely financial impact of shortening product lifetimes).
28
The following decades have witnessed an increasing number of addi-
tional, less economic-focused reports that indicate the existence of obso-
lescence strategies.
29
In more recent years, environmental concerns
linked to sustainable production and use of goods has intensified the
¨ ¨ ¨
P
RINZIP
D
ER
G
EPLANTEN
O
BSOLESZENZ
13 (Orange Press 2013); Jana Valant, European Parlia-
mentary Research Serv., Planned Obsolescence: Exploring the Issue, at 3 (May 2016) (“One
of the last remaining examples of the old bulb, the Centennial Light Bulb, manufactured by the
Shelby Electric Company and installed in 1901, still continues to function 24 hours a day in
2016.”).
25
See, e.g., Monopolies & Restrictive Practices Comm’n, Report on the Supply of Elec-
tric Lamps, at 141–42 (Oct. 4, 1951).
26
Markus Krajewski, The Great Lightbulb Conspiracy, IEEE S
PECTRUM
(Sept. 24,
2014), https://spectrum.ieee.org/tech-history/dawn-of-electronics/the-great-lightbulb-
conspiracy.
27
See Valant, supra note 24.
28
See e.g., Peter L. Swan, Optimum Durability, Second-Hand Markets, and Planned
Obsolescence, 80 J. P
OL
. E
CON
. 575 (1972); Jeremy Bulow, An Economic Theory of Planned
Obsolescence, 101 Q.J. E
CON
. 729 (1986); Winand Emons, On the Limitation of Warranty
Duration, 37 J. I
NDUS
. E
CON
. 287 (1989); Michael Waldman, A New Perspective on Planned
Obsolescence, 108 Q.J. E
CON
. 273 (1993); Gregory E. Goering, Durability Choice under De-
mand Uncertainty, 60 E
CONOMICA
397 (1993); Arthur Fishman, Neil Gandal & Oz Shy,
Planned Obsolescence as an Engine of Technological Progress, 41 J. I
NDUSTRIAL
E
CON
. 361
(1993); Jay Pil Choi, Network Externality, Compatibility Choice, and Planned Obsolescence,
42 J. I
NDUS
. E
CON
. 167 (1994); Michael Waldman, Planned Obsolescence and the R&D Deci-
sion, 27 RAND J. E
CON
. 583 (1996); Arthur Fishman & Rafael Rob, Product Innovation by a
Durable-Good Monopoly, 31 RAND J. E
CON
. 237 (2000); Atsuo Utaka, Planned Obsoles-
cence and Marketing Strategy, 21 M
ANAGERIAL
& D
ECISION
E
CON
. 339 (2000); Paul A. Grout
& In-Uck Park, Competitive Planned Obsolescence, 36 RAND J. E
CON
. 596 (2005); Atsuo
Utaka, Durable-Goods Warranties and Social Welfare, 22 J.L. E
CON
. & O
RG
. 508 (2006);
Roland Strausz, Planned Obsolescence as an Incentive Device for Unobservable Quality, 119
E
CON
. J. 1405 (2009); Chun-Hui Miao, Tying, Compatibility and Planned Obsolescence, 58 J.
I
NDUS
. E
CON
. 579 (2010); Yijuan Chen, Innovation Frequency of Durable Complementary
Goods, 48 J. M
ATHEMATICAL
E
CON
. 407 (2012).
29
See, e.g., Centre Europ´een de la Consommation & Zentrum f¨ur Europ¨aischen Ver-
braucherschutz e.V., L’Obsolescence Programm´ee ou les D´erives de la Soci´et´e de Consomma-
tion, at 3, (April 2013), https://www.cec-zev.eu/fileadmin/user_upload/eu-consommateurs/
PDFs/publications/etudes_et_rapports/Etude-Obsolescence.pdf; Taiwo K. Aladeojebi, Planned
Obsolescence, 4 I
NTL
. J. S
CI
. & E
NGINEERING
R
ES
. 1504, 1505–06 (2013); S
TEFAN
S
CHRIDDE
,
M
URKS
? N
EIN
D
ANKE
! W
AS WIR TUN ONNEN
,
DAMIT DIE
D
INGE BESSER WERDEN
(2014);
24
See, e.g., J
URGEN
R
EU
b & C
OSIMA
D
ANNORITZER
, K
AUFEN
F
UR
D
IE
M
ULLHALDE
: D
AS
K
¨
Adrian Porter, Are Washing Machines Built to Fail? We Chart the Rise of the Throwaway
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 12 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
494
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
planned obsolescence debate. This came at a time when sustainability
gained importance as a broad international construct. In 2000, the World
Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBCSD) issued a report
on “eco-efficiency.”
30
Bearing in mind that the WBSCD operates as a
platform for businesses, it does not come as a surprise that the report did
not directly address the problem of planned obsolescence. The report fo-
cused on the environmental soundness of production processes rather
than the durability of products.
31
Nevertheless, the shared view of the
WBSCD members, expressed in the report as an emphasis on strategies
of eco-friendly production,
32
indicates the direction responsible-minded
producers should be heading. They noted that an increasing number of
producers have identified a market niche for ecologically friendly strate-
gies, and that this recognition may be a sign of a slow shift towards
increased environmental awareness relating to the durability of goods.
33
Eventually, policy-makers and legal academics began to exchange views
on how to counteract or limit planned obsolescence.
34
It should also be noted that (just as is the case with guarantees) the
phenomenon of planned obsolescence should be understood in multi-
layered ways. As early as 1960, Vance Packard in his book, The Waste
Makers, differentiated types of obsolescence strategies—“obsolescence
of desirability,” “obsolescence of function,” and “obsolescence of
quality.”
35
Appliance, W
HICH
? N
EWS
, Jun. 17, 2015, https://www.which.co.uk/news/2015/06/are-washing
-machines-built-to-fail-406177/.
30
World Bus. Council for Sustainable Dev. (WBCSD), Eco-Efficiency: Creating More
Value with Less Impact (Oct. 2000).
31
See id. at 16.
32
See id. at 28–29.
33
See id. at 17–19. See also Joseph Guiltinan, Creative Destruction and Destructive
Creations: Environmental Ethics and Planned Obsolescence, 89 J. B
US
. E
THICS
19 (2009)
(discussing the interplay of sustainable production and planned obsolescence).
34
See, e.g., Gerhard Wortmann & Peter Schimikowski, Geplanter Produktverschlei
b
und b¨urgerliches Recht [Planned Product Wear and Civil Law], 16 Zeitschrift f ¨ur Wirtschaft-
srecht 978 (1985) [hereinafter Planned Product Wear and Civil Law]; Schriftenreihe Des In-
stituts Fur Europaisches Wirtschafts- Und Verbraucherrecht e.V. [Series of the Institute for
European Economic and Consumer Law e.V.], Obsoleszenz interdisziplin¨ar: Vorzeitiger
Verschleib aus Sicht von Wissenschaft und Praxis [Obsolescence Interdisciplinary: Premature
Wear from the Perspective of Science and Practice] (Tobias Br¨onneke & Andrea Wechsler
eds., 2015); Wrbka, supra note 11; El´eonore Maitre-Ekern & Carl Dalhammar, Regulating
Planned Obsolescence: A Review of Legal Approaches to Increase Product Durability and
Reparability in Europe, 25 R
EV
. E
UR
. C
OMMUNITY
& I
NT
L
E
NVTL
. L. 378, 379 (2016); Ana¨ıs
Michel, Product Lifetimes through the Various Legal Approaches within the EU Context: Re-
cent Initiatives Against Planned Obsolescence, P
LATE
266, 269 (Conny Bakker & Ruth Mugge
eds., 2017).
35
V
ANCE
P
ACKARD
, T
HE
W
ASTE
M
AKERS
55 (1960). For some more recent contribu-
tions that include slightly differently nuanced categories, which nevertheless follow Packard’s
basic classification, see, e.g., John R. Mansfield & James A. Pinder, “Economic” and “Func-
tional” Obsolescence: Their Characteristics and Impacts on Valuation Practice, 26 P
ROP
.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 13 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
495
From a guarantee perspective, it is obsolescence of quality that is
most relevant. Here, the lifetime of a product ends prematurely because
of technical issues. In cases of obsolescence of desirability and function,
on the other hand, the good still runs flawlessly. Users choose to stop
using the still usable item because they feel that they “need” a follow-up
product—either “convinced” by marketing strategies (obsolescence of
desirability) or because the newer product would objectively show differ-
ent, additional or enhanced technical functions (obsolescence of func-
tion). Neither legal guarantees nor EWSCs can be applied to remedy the
end of the use of a product in cases that do not relate to qualitative issues.
II. M
ARKETPLACE AND
R
EGULATORY
L
ANDSCAPES OF
EWSC
S IN THE
U
NITED
S
TATES
,
THE
EU,
AND
E
UROPEAN
M
EMBER
S
TATES
This Part examines the EWSC marketplace, as well as the existing
regulatory schemes in the United States, the EU, and some EU Member
States. It first examines the size and characteristics of the different mar-
kets, as well as the unevenness of the regulatory schemes aimed at pro-
tecting consumer abuse.
A. United States
This Section first provides empirical evidence of the size and depth
of the American market for EWSCs. It will show the types of products
that EWSCs are most associated with, as well as the fluidity over time of
the size of the market for different categories of products. It will also
show the revenues generated by the sale of EWSCs and the allocation of
the revenues between the different players on the sales side of the trans-
actions: manufacturers, retailers, third-party insurers. The second part ex-
amines the mix of regulatory authorities and laws that relate to the
EWSC industry in the United States.
1. Relevance of EWSCs in the U.S.
The EWSC industry has reached the menu of items sold by Amazon
in the area of electronics. A website dedicated to EWSCs for electronic
products numbers over 20,000 entries.
36
As of 2014, the EWSC market
in the U.S. had reached $39.5 billion dollars, with an annual growth rate
of 7.33%.
37
As Chart 1 shows, the auto-related EWSC share of the mar-
ket is about 40%, followed by mobile phones (22%), electronics (18%),
M
GT
. 191, 193 (2008); Planned Product Wear and Civil Law, supra note 34, at 978 (discuss-
ing qualitative obsolescence and psychological obsolescence).
36
Search results for extended warranties, A
MAZON
, https://www.amazon.com (search in
search bar for “extended warranties”) (last visited Jan. 28, 2019).
37
Mid-Year Service Contract Report, W
ARRANTY
W
EEK
(Oct. 9, 2014), https://
www.warrantyweek.com/archive/ww20141009.html; Abhishek Yadav, Extended Warranty &
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 14 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
Auto
40%
Mobile Phone
22%
Consumer
Electronics
18%
Home/Appliance
8%
496
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
personal computers (12%), home warranties (4.6%), and appliance war-
ranties (3.4%).
38
Between 2008 and 2014, U.S. economic growth aver-
aged 2.2% per year, while the growth of the EWSC industry averaged
8.33% per year.
39
The sales of extended warranties on mobile phones
increased on average 28.07% per year from 2009–2013.
40
C
HART
1: U.S. C
ONSUMER
EWSC I
NDUSTRY
(2014): $39.5 B
ILLION
PCs
12%
The insurer of EWSCs varies and includes the following: retailer
protection plans, such as the Best Buy Geek Squad Protection Plan;
41
manufacturer or OEM-branded protection plans,
42
such as Apple Care;
and third-party, direct to-the-consumer providers’ protection plans, such
as Assurant 360.
43
Commonly, plans include three parties other than the
purchaser of the EWSC. These include the seller (retailer), the obligor or
party responsible for paying the claims under the EWSC, and third-party
networks of service providers (companies that do the actual work of re-
Service Contract Industry USA 5, S
LIDE
S
HARE
(July 11, 2015), https://www.slideshare.net/
AbhishekYadav23/extended-warranty-industry-in-us.
38
Yadav, supra note 37, at 5.
39
Id. at 6.
40
See id. at 11.
41
See Geek Squad Terms and Conditions, B
EST
B
UY
, https://www.bestbuy.com/usw/
termsconditions/anonymous (use drop-down menus to select plan based on plan type and date
range).
42
OEMs are not actually the “original manufacturer” of the equipment, but are actually a
company who has a relationship with the original manufacture to resell that manufacturer’s
product under its own name and branding. Usually OEM products are the same quality as the
retail versions, but warranties may be different. See Original Equipment Manufacturer—OEM,
I
NVESTOPEDIA
, https://www.investopedia.com/terms/o/oem.asp (last visited Nov. 16, 2018).
43
See, e.g., Assurant 360
°
Protection Summary, A
SSURANT
S
OLUTIONS
(March 2014),
https://www.assurantsolutions.com/extended-warranty/~/media/Files/TCs/amazon_sample_
terms_and_conditions_0314.ashx (containing sample Terms and Conditions for an Assurant
360 Protection Plan that is purchased through Amazon).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 15 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
497
pair and replace).
44
One estimate of the allocation of the purchase price
for EWSCs shows 50% is retained by the seller (retailer), 30% is allo-
cated to the insurance company (underwriter), and 20% for the adminis-
trator (see Chart 2: ESC Premium Split).
45
Within the 30% received by the insurance company, the money is
allocated as follows: fees of 5.25%, payment of claims 19.8%, and a
buffer or reserve fund of 4.95%.
46
The allocations of the premiums and
allocation within the insurance share of the premium depend on the prod-
uct and factors such as the product’s estimated lifespan (planned obsoles-
cence) and the length of protection provided by the EWSC.
47
In general,
Chart 2 shows that based upon the probability calculation (an estimate of
the likelihood of EWSC claims), which acts as a surrogate for planned
obsolescence, only 19.8% of the purchase price is used to make repairs
or to satisfy claims. The reserve fund not used to pay for an unexpectedly
high number of claims or costs of repair become additional profit for the
insurance company.
C
HART
2: ESC P
REMIUM
S
PLIT
Sales Agent
50%
Insurance
Company
30%
Administrator
20%
This tripartite scheme is not consumer friendly. In the automobile
sale, the car purchaser buys the policy from the car dealer, but any claim
must be made to the manufacturer or a third-party insurer, and often a
third company performs the actual repair work.
48
The retailer simply
44
See id. at 1–2, 6.
45
The SAFE Guys, supra note 2. Some terms, like “administrator,” may be defined by
state statute. See, e.g., N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
§ 7902(b) (McKinney 2018) (“‘Administrator means
any person designated by a provider to be responsible for administration of service contracts,
including servicing, claims management and processing, recordkeeping, customer service and
collection of fees.”).
46
The SAFE Guys, supra note 2.
47
Id.
48
Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 16 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
498
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
takes half of the premium paid as pure profit with no continuing obliga-
tions. Further, under this system, the car owner technically cannot make
a claim or deal directly with the repair company since it has no privity of
contract.
49
This is because there is no contractual relationship between
the repair company and the customer. The customer, under the common
law, cannot make the argument that she is a third-party beneficiary
50
since she has direct privity to the insurer and thus has an avenue of re-
course. Thus, the car owner has to work through the insurer, and in some
cases is required to file a new claim in order to “repair a repair.”
51
As
such, a common complaint relates to the prolonged time for automobile
repair or for the car owner to be reimbursed after paying the repairs up-
front; not uncommonly, the repair work may take a month or more.
52
This is likely due to a long queue as insurers are incentivized to lower
costs by using a limited number of service providers.
53
The retailer in this tripartite scenario obtains a windfall by receiving
half the purchase price of the EWSC with no follow-up responsibilities.
This creates a moral hazard because it incentives the retailer to pressure
the consumer to buy an EWSC that is often not in the interest of the
consumer. In some cases, the car dealer makes as much on selling the
EWSC as it does selling the automobile.
54
The hard sell tactics utilized
are generally not subject to government regulation because any such reg-
ulations are directed to the principal (insurer) and not to its agent (re-
tailer).
55
The only claim that may be lodged against the retailer is
common law misrepresentation or fraud. This is unlikely to be successful
since the sale tactics do not amount to a material misrepresentation of
fact. The other avenue of recourse in American, but not English,
56
com-
49
The privity doctrine holds that only direct parties to a contract have standing to sue for
breach of contract. 3 E. A
LLAN
F
ARNSWORTH
, F
ARNSWORTH ON
C
ONTRACTS
5 (3d ed. 2004).
50
There are exceptions to the privity doctrine when an outside party is recognized as a
third-party beneficiary. Professor Farnswoth traces the common law’s third-party beneficiary
rule to the 1677 case of Dutton v. Poole, 83 Eng. Rep. 523 (K.B. 1677). Id. at 7.
51
See FTC, supra note 7.
52
The U.S. Federal Trade Commission warns: “If the auto service contract doesn’t spec-
ify how long reimbursement usually takes, ask. Find out who settles claims in case you have a
dispute with the service contract provider and need to use a dispute resolution program.” Id.
53
Nancy A. Lutz & V. Padmanabhan, Why Do We Observe Minimal Warranties?, 14
M
ARKETING
S
CI
. 417, 418 (1995).
54
NADA Data 2017: Annual Financial Profile of America’s Franchised New-Car Deal-
erships, N
AT
L
A
UTO
. D
EALERS
A
SS
N
3, https://www.nada.org/2017NADAdata/ (“Service,
parts and body shop gross as % of total gross” hit 49% in 2017.).
55
For example, if the third-party insurer is an insurance company, then it must meet the
capitalization requirements mandated by state insurance law. See, e.g., N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
§ 7903(c) (McKinney 2018).
56
Larry A. DiMatteo, A Study of Judicial Reasoning—When Penalties are not Penal-
ties?, 85 G
EO
. W
ASH
. L. R
EV
. 1846, 1857 (2017) (English common law does not recognize
unconscionability as an independent policy doctrine. However, the term “unconscionable” is a
free-floating construct found in court decisions striking terms in consumer contracts.).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 17 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
499
mon law is the doctrine of unconscionability.
57
However, such a claim is
likely to fail due to a lack of substantive unconscionability because the
price alone is rarely enough to be considered unconscionable in a market
economy. Another avenue of recourse exists in state “price gouging”
statutes, but these statutes target overpricing in cases involving a natural
disaster or emergency.
58
Although contract law does not provide a de-
gree of certainty in policing EWSCs, it does have constructs (expanded
privity, misrepresentation, and unconscionability, as well as current war-
ranty law) that could be modified to allow contract law to regulate
EWSCs.
2. Regulatory Landscape of EWSCs in the U.S.
In the U.S., the regulatory landscape relating to EWSCs is a haphaz-
ard mix of federal and state regulations. Many of these regulations do not
specifically target the EWSC; rather, they are extrapolated from long-
existing regulatory schemes, such as insurance and warranty law.
59
There
is no single regulatory authority at the federal or state levels whose scope
extends to all legal issues relating to the EWSC industry. Such a piece-
meal approach leaves numerous gaps in the regulation of the EWSCs, as
well as incongruences in approach among the American states. In sum,
the EWSC marketplace has not been immune from government regula-
tion, but the level of consumer protection is at a lower threshold than
consumer protection laws tailored for specific industries and issues.
Since there is no independent consumer contract law or standard
terms regulation in the U.S. as is found in Europe,
60
regulation of
EWSCs is relegated to a fragmented legal regime including common
law, as well as state and federal regulatory law. In the end, the below
review will show that there are gaps in the regulation of EWSCs and the
protection of consumers from abusive selling tactics and one-sided
contracts.
a. Federal Warranty Law
Federal warranty law in the U.S. is encased in the Magnuson-Moss
Act (MMA).
61
It is important to understand that EWSCs are treated dif-
ferently than warranties under the law. The U.S. Federal Trade Commis-
57
U.C.C. § 2-302.
58
See, e.g., F
LA
. S
TAT
. § 501.160 (2011) (“[D]uring a state of emergency, it is unlawful
to sell, lease, offer to sell, or offer for lease essential commodities, dwelling units, or self-
storage facilities for an amount that grossly exceeds the average price for that commodity
during the 30 days before the declaration of the state of emergency.”).
59
See FTC, supra note 7.
60
See, e.g., Council Directive 93/13/EEC of 5 April 1993 on Unfair Terms in Consumer
Contracts, 1993 O.J. (L 95) 29 (EC) [hereinafter UCTD].
61
Magnuson-Moss Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 2301–12 (1975).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 18 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
500
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
sion describes a service contract as “a promise to perform (or pay for)
certain repairs or services.”
62
“Sometimes called an ‘extended warranty,’
a service contract is not a warranty as defined by federal law.”
63
Warran-
ties are considered part of the product, while EWSCs are treated as inde-
pendent of the underlying sale and purchase contract, and, therefore the
MMA does not apply to them.
64
A brief review is undertaken here to see
if some of the law’s features could be useful in the regulation of EWSCs,
despite its failure to directly regulate EWSCs. The MMA requires that
warranty terms and conditions be presented in a conspicuous manner and
written in plain language. The concept of conspicuousness is also found
in the Uniform Commercial Code, as discussed below.
Unfortunately, the MMA’s coverage of warranties is broad, but
short on specifics. The law is more about form, than substance. It does
not provide minimum standards for warranties; it mandates how warran-
ties and warranty disclaimers are to be presented to the consumer.
65
Any
consumer disclosure requirements only apply to the manufacturer and
not to the retailer-seller.
66
Also, the manufacturer-seller of an EWSC
cannot disclaim the implied warranties, but agents (such as automobile
dealers) may disclaim such warranties.
67
b. State Law: Common Law of Contracts and Uniform
Commercial Code (UCC)
In the U.S., the common law, found in individual state laws, fails to
distinguish between commercial and consumer contracts and except for a
few exceptions in Article 2 of the UCC, does not distinguish between
commercial and consumer sale of goods.
68
Up to the present, despite a
62
FTC, supra note 7.
63
Id.
64
See § 2301(8).
65
See § 2303(a) (requiring plain language and conspicuousness).
66
See §§ 2301(5), 2303(a).
67
See § 2308(a).
68
The handful of provisions in the UCC that provides additional protections is collec-
tively noted as the merchant-consumer distinction. Except for these few provisions, the UCC
applies equally to commercial and consumer transactions. See generally, Ingrid M. Hillinger,
The Article 2 Merchant Rules: Karl Llewellyn’s Attempt to Achieve the Good, the True, the
Beautiful in Commercial Law, 73 G
EO
. L.J. 1141, 1184 (1985) (“Other scholars as well have
noted the doctrinal confusion and poor results that flow from a unitary approach to situations
involving different issues and policy concerns.”); Zipporah B. Wiseman, The Limits of Vision:
Karl Llewellyn and the Merchant Rules, 100 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 465, 520 (1987) (suggesting
Llewellyn believed that merchant associations wielded too much power in the unregulated
marketplace). While the UCC does not define Consumer, it defines Merchant as “a person who
deals in goods of the kind or otherwise by his occupation holds himself out as having knowl-
edge or skill peculiar to the practices or goods involved in the transaction or to whom such
knowledge or skill may be attributed by his employment of an agent or broker or other inter-
mediary who by his occupation holds himself out as having such knowledge or skill.” U.C.C.
§ 2-104(1).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 19 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
501
host of consumer protection laws, American contract law remains ge-
neric in nature without any recognized body of consumer contract law.
69
The exception is that the merchant-consumer distinction plays a role in
the use of the doctrine of unconscionability found in the UCC and, ap-
plied by analogy to other types of contracts, is in practice used exclu-
sively to void terms in consumer contracts.
70
This is despite the fact that
as written, UCC § 2-302 equally applies to commercial contracts.
71
The
bargaining power and informational imbalances found in consumer con-
tracts have become the linchpin for the application of the doctrine of
unconscionability.
72
However, it is important to note that the general rule
is that one-sided (pro-merchant) terms in a consumer contract are en-
forced and that the unconscionability doctrine is only applied in ad hoc
cases, and cannot itself be considered a form of standard terms regula-
tion.
73
In American contract law, there is no “fairness concept,” as found
in the EU Unfair Terms in Consumer Contracts
74
or “surprising terms”
principle, as found in German law.
75
A seller of goods is not obligated to provide a warranty. However,
any contract language that attempts to limit the scope of an express war-
ranty is unenforceable.”
76
The UCC implies certain warranties, whether
or not an express warranty is provided.
77
The implied warranty of
merchantability
78
and implied warranty for a particular purpose
79
are at-
tached to sale of goods contracts unless expressly disclaimed. However,
69
For example, fine print terms, often incorporated by reference, are enforceable
whether they are found in consumer or commercial contracts. See Int’l Ass’n of Machinists &
Aerospace Workers v. ISP Chems., 261 F. App’x 841, 848 (6th Cir. 2008).
70
See U.C.C. §§ 2-104, 2-302.
71
Id. § 2-302.
72
Charles L. Knapp, Unconscionability in American Contract Law: A Twenty-First-Cen-
tury Survey, in C
OMMERCIAL
C
ONTRACT
L
AW
T
RANSATLANTIC
P
ERSPECTIVES
309 (Larry A.
DiMatteo et al. eds., 2013) (noting that the U.S. Supreme Court has narrowed the use of
unconscionability to void arbitration clauses in consumer contracts).
73
See U.C.C. § 2-302; see also Paul Bennet Marrow, Contractual Unconscionability:
Identifying and Understanding Its Potential Elements, 72 N.Y. S
T
. B.J. 18, 22 (2000).
74
See UCTD, supra note 60; see also CRD, supra note 21.
75
B
¨
URGERLICHES
G
ESETZBUCH
[BGB] [C
IVIL
C
ODE
], § 305c, translation at https://ger
manlawarchive.iuscomp.org/?p=632 (Ger.) [hereinafter BGB] (“Surprising and ambiguous
clauses” state that standard business terms that “are so unusual that the contractual partner of
the user could not be expected to have reckoned with them, do not form part of the contract.”).
76
U.C.C. § 2-316(1) (“Words or conduct relevant to the creation of an express warranty
and words or conduct tending to negate or limit warranty shall be construed wherever reasona-
ble as consistent with each other; but . . . negation or limitation is inoperative to the extent that
such construction is unreasonable.”).
77
§§ 2-314, 2-315.
78
§ 2-314.
79
§ 2-315.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 20 14-JUN-19 7:19
502
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
§ 2-316(2)
80
limits the effectiveness of a disclaimer. First, to exclude the
implied warranty of merchantability the disclaimer must explicitly use
the word “merchantability.”
81
Second, the disclaimer language must be
presented in a conspicuous manner.
82
But, these requirements are simply
formalities, easily surmounted by boilerplate disclaimer clauses. How-
ever, violations of the warranty provisions of the UCC make manufactur-
ers susceptible to claims under § 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act
(Act).
83
The Act simply states in broad terms that any “unfair or decep-
tive acts or practices in or affecting commerce, are hereby declared un-
lawful.”
84
The Act assigns regulatory authority to the Federal Trade
Commission.
85
Violations can be punished by penalties of $10,000 to be
collected by the Attorney General through civil actions.
86
Again, unfortunately warranty law does not currently regulate
EWSCs since it focuses on product warranties, which are part and parcel
to the product being sold. EWSCs are considered a separate product from
the standard warranty provided in the sale. The EWSC is independent of
the sale of the good for which the consumer pays an additional price.
However, there is little reason that the conspicuousness and plain lan-
guage requirements should not be extended to EWSCs.
In the end, the lack of federal regulation leaves it to state law to
provide governance. Unfortunately, such state regulation is also lacking
or sporadic, especially given that there is no existing model law on the
subject. The state regulatory law closest to EWSCs is found in insurance
law. For example, New York Insurance Law applies to certain service
contracts and commercial guarantees, which is discussed in the next
section.
c. State Regulation: New York Insurance Law
Technically, state insurance laws regulate EWSCs. Given its promi-
nence in the area of commercial law, New York State (NYS) Insurance
law will be reviewed here. NYS Insurance Law makes a distinction be-
tween warranty and service contracts. Generally, insurance law does not
cover warranties, but the NYS Department of Insurance regulates service
contracts.
87
The law defines a service contract as an “agreement, for a
80
§ 2-316(2) (“[T]o exclude or modify the implied warranty of merchantability or any
part of it the language must mention merchantability and in case of a writing must be
conspicuous . . . .”).
81
Id.
82
Id.
83
15 U.S.C. § 45(a) (2012) (codifying Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act).
84
Id.
85
Id.
86
Id.
87
See, e.g., N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
§ 7901 (McKinney 2012).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 21 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
503
separate or additional consideration, for a specific duration to perform
the repair, replacement or maintenance of property, or indemnification
for repair, replacement or maintenance, due to a defect in materials or
workmanship or wear and tear.”
88
However, that regulation simply requires registration, certification,
licensing, and conformity to solvency regulations.
89
The third-party in-
surer-provider of the service contract is required to meet these require-
ments, but the retailer or seller, and the contractor providing the services
or doing the repairs are not. However, a company independent of the
third-party insurer if “it actually obligates itself to make repairs and
maintenance under a service contract, [ ] would have to register as a ser-
vice contract provider.”
90
NYS Insurance Law does not require a service contract provider to
file their rates and contract forms for review by the Department. Article
79, entitled “Service Contracts,” states that its purposes are to “create a
legal framework within which service contracts may be sold in this state;
encourage the marketing and developing of more economical and effec-
tive means of providing services under service contracts; and permit and
encourage fair and effective competition among different systems of pro-
viding and paying for these services.”
91
Article 79 authorizes the Super-
intendent of Insurance to enforce the law by, for example, conducting
investigations and issuing cease and desist orders.
92
The key question is what distinguishes extended warranties from a
service contract under NYS Insurance Law? First, the service contract is
independent of the product itself. However, if the manufacturer is the
underwriter or provider of the service contract, then the contract is not
covered under insurance law.
93
Second, if the EWSC coverage insures
against a risk external (“fortuitous risk”) from the product, then it is
deemed to be a service contract.
94
In one case, a third-party insurer pro-
vided protection for restaurant equipment against damage due to a fire.
95
The Office of General Counsel held that the product was a service con-
88
N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
§ 7902(k) (McKinney 2012).
89
N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
§ 7903(c) (McKinney 2012) (requiring that the insurer maintain a re-
serve fund not less than 5% of the price of the contracts sold).
90
N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
art. 79 (McKinney 2012); Office of Gen. Counsel, N.Y. Ins. Dep’t, Re:
Licensing/Registration Requirements for Service Contract Providers, D
EP
T
F
IN
. S
ERVS
. (June
3, 2002), https://www.dfs.ny.gov/insurance/ogco2002/rg206033.htm [hereinafter Service Con-
tract Providers].
91
N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
§ 7901.
92
N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
§7910(b)(1).
93
Service Contract Providers, supra note 90.
94
Office of Gen. Counsel, N.Y. Ins. Dep’t, Re: Marketing an Extended Warranty Pro-
gram, D
EP
T
F
IN
. S
ERVS
. (Sept. 17, 2007), https://www.dfs.ny.gov/insurance/ogco2007/
rg070915.htm.
95
Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 22 14-JUN-19 7:19
504
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
tract because the third-party undertook an obligation that involved a for-
tuitous risk, thereby, making the contract a type of insurance.
96
Some EWSCs may restrict transfers of the contract to future own-
ers. For example: a home purchaser or owner buys an EWSC. Does the
purchaser-owner have the right to transfer the contract when she resells
the home with time remaining on the EWSC? If not, should the third-
party insurer be required to refund a pro rata amount of the contract
price? NYS Insurance Law simply requires that service contracts state
the terms, restrictions or conditions governing the transferability of such
contracts.
97
But, other than this disclosure requirement, as a general mat-
ter, the transferability of a service contract depends upon the provisions
in the specific contract in question, including a non-transferability provi-
sion.
98
The law also requires the service contract to specify any limita-
tions on the right to terminate the service contract by the provider or
contract holder and the right, if any, to receive a refund.
99
The law does
not deal with the issue of whether the seller or provider of the EWSC
should be able to assign the contract to another party, which may provide
lower cost and lower quality services.
A more proactive provision of NYS Insurance Law provides a right
of rescission in which a purchaser of a service contract has ten, and
sometimes twenty, days to rescind the contract unless the purchaser al-
ready filed a claim.
100
The third-party insurer must give a refund in full
96
Id. Another New York case involved the sale of a new tire with a “road hazard war-
ranty program.” Office of Gen. Counsel, N.Y. Ins. Dep’t, Re: The Product Warranty of a Tire
Product, D
EP
T
F
IN
. S
ERVS
. (May 11, 2004), https://www.dfs.ny.gov/insurance/ogco2004/
rg040512.htm. The product included placing a sealant on the tire to provide added protection.
Id. But, it is not the product or sealant being warranted; instead, it is insurance against the tire
rupturing due to an external event that is being provided. The product warranty was not related
to any defect in materials or workmanship in the tires; rather, it was based upon the product’s
failure to prevent tire damage from road hazards. The Office of General Counsel reasoned:
“[If] the tire be damaged due to a road hazard, it is not because the product did not work as
intended to prevent drying out or rotting of the tire, but rather it is because there was some-
thing in the roadway, an intervening ‘fortuitous event,’ within the meaning of the Insurance
Law.” Id. Road hazards, such as a nail on the road, are outside the control of either the pro-
vider of the warranty or the car dealer who sells the warranty. Since the warranty was indepen-
dent of the product and insured against a fortuitous event, it was held that the warranty was a
service contract. In either situation, the service contract provider and any administrator liability
were subject to NYS Insurance Law, and thereby liable for the damage to the tire since it was
due to a protected occurrence. N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
§ 7902 (McKinney 2012) (Administrator is
defined as a “person designated by a provider to be responsible for administration of service
contracts, including servicing, claims management and processing, recordkeeping, customer
service and collection of fees.”).
97
N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
§ 7905(j) (McKinney 1998).
98
Office of Gen. Counsel, N.Y. Ins. Dep’t, Transferability of Service Contract, D
EP
T
F
IN
. S
ERVS
. (Mar. 13, 2008), https://www.dfs.ny.gov/insurance/ogco2008/rg080311.htm.
99
N.Y. C
OMP
. C
ODES
R. & R
EGS
. tit. 11, § 390.5(a) (1999).
100
N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
art. 79 (McKinney 2000); N.Y. C
OMP
. C
ODES
R. & R
EGS
. tit. 11
§§ 390.0–390.13 (1999) (Regulation 155); N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
§ 7903(e) (McKinney 2012).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 23 14-JUN-19 7:19
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
505
within thirty days after receiving the notice of rescission.
101
If the third-
party insurer-provider fails to make a timely refund, then it must pay the
holder an additional ten percent, as well as an additional ten-percent pen-
alty for each subsequent month until the refund is paid.
102
d. Restatement of Consumer Contract Law
The EWSC is essentially a consumer standard form contract. As
previously stated, there are no general standard term regulations or body
of consumer contract law as is found in Europe. However, the American
Law Institute recently sponsored the drafting of a Restatement of Con-
sumer Contract Law (Consumer Restatement).
103
The new Restatement
project can be seen as a supplement to the Restatement (Second) of Con-
tracts
104
and UCC, dedicated solely to consumers. The reporters of the
Consumer Restatement recognize that “consumer contracts present a fun-
damental challenge to the law of contracts, arising from the asymmetry
in information, sophistication, and stakes between the parties to these
contracts—the business and the consumer.”
105
They list two techniques
for preventing consumer abuse in contracts: (1) assuring mutual assent
by focusing on the rules that determine how terms are adopted and which
processes a business can use to introduce and to modify terms in the
agreement; and (2) the use of mandatory restrictions over the substance
of the deal—rules that limit the discretion of the business in drafting
contract terms and the setting of boundaries to permissible con-
tracting.
106
In essence, the Consumer Restatement project is a soft law
form of European standard terms regulation.
107
The goal of the Consumer Restatement is to take the first steps in
creating a separate body of consumer contract law: first, by recognizing
specific contract law rules that only apply to consumer transactions; and
second, by incorporating existing government regulations of the con-
sumer market place into a standalone consumer contract law. This would
include the following: (1) formulating “principles for punitive treatment
101
N.Y. I
NS
. L
AW
§ 7903(e) (Mckinney 2012).
102
Id.
103
See Restatement of the Law, Consumer Contracts, A
M
. L
AW
I
NST
., https://
www.ali.org/projects/show/consumer-contracts (All nine sections of the Restatement have
been drafted, and the initial draft was presented for discussion at the 2017 ALI Annual Meet-
ing. It is expected to be re-presented at the 2019 Meeting.).
104
R
ESTATEMENT
(S
ECOND
)
OF
C
ONTRACTS
(A
M
. L
AW
I
NST
. 1981).
105
Project Feature: Restatement of the Law, Consumer Contracts, T
HE
ALI A
DVISER
(May 2017), http://www.thealiadviser.org/consumer-contracts.
106
Id.
107
Id. (Restatement Draft including sections entitled “Adoption of Standard Contract
Terms” (§ 2) and “Modification of Standard Contract Terms” (§ 3).).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 24 14-JUN-19 7:19
506
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
of some types of willful breaches of consumer contracts;”
108
(2)
“[u]nify[ing] the framework” for developing rules mandating pro-con-
sumer terms and banning terms that are deemed to be abusive;”
109
(3)
clarifying the contours of the unconscionability doctrine, including how
it applies in the area of arbitration;
110
and (4) “[d]istilling the common
principles that ought to guide” courts in applying the FTC Act, state laws
prohibiting “unfair or deceptive” acts or practices and the Dodd-Frank
111
prohibition on “unfair, deceptive or abusive” acts or practices.
112
Unfortunately, the proposed Consumer Restatement places empha-
sis on the first of the above two techniques by re-emphasizing the impor-
tance of consent and de-emphasizing the importance of mandatory
regulations aimed at setting boundaries of impressible consumer con-
tracting (restrictive consumer-specific rules). For example, § 2 provides
rules on the adoption of standard contract terms.
113
It provides that a
consumer signifies assent to the transaction as long as she is given rea-
sonable notice of the standard terms and a reasonable opportunity to re-
view them.
114
This does little to ensure the quality of the consent under
the reality that most consumers do not read or understand such terms;
this is especially common where the standard contract is long and
detailed.
The unitary concept of consent, generally resting on a person’s
agreement or signing of a contract, fails to recognize the absence of true
consent, understanding of agreement found in many consumer contracts.
The Restatement does provide for the buttressing of consent through pre-
contract disclosures.
115
Thus, the unitary construction of consent is modi-
fied in consumer contracts to mean only consent that is “adequately in-
formed.”
116
In the case of EWSCs, disclosures as to the risk of needing
repairs, costs, and rights would be helpful, but only if the disclosures are
108
Consumer Fin. Services Grp., ALI Launches Restatement Project for Consumer Con-
tracts, B
ALLARD
S
PAHR
(Dec. 6, 2012), https://www.ballardspahr.com/alertspublications/
legalalerts/2012-12-06-ali-launches-restatement-project-for-consumer-contracts.aspx.
109
Id.
110
Id. (“[O]ne goal will be to translate research on consumer decision-making, and on the
limits of consumer understanding, into specific guidelines for the courts”).
111
Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111-203,
124 Stat. 1376. (July 21, 2010). Part of the long title of the law that states that one of its
purposes is “to protect consumers from abusive financial services practices.” It established the
Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) as an agency responsible for consumer protec-
tion in the financial sector.
112
Id.
113
Florence Marotta-Wurgler, Omri Ben-Sharar & Oren Bar-Gill, Adoption of Standard
Contract Terms, T
HE
ALI A
DVISER
(Apr. 27, 2017), http://www.thealiadviser.org/consumer-
contracts/adoption-standard-contract-terms.
114
Id.
115
Id.
116
Alan S. Kaplinsky & Brian Slagle, Proposed Consumer Contracts Restatement Criti-
qued at ALI Annual Meeting, C
ONSUMER
F
IN
. M
ONITOR
(June 2, 2017), https://
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 25 14-JUN-19 7:19
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
507
meaningful. For example, the disclosure should state whether the pur-
chaser has a right of rescission and whether the contract is transferable.
Also, disclosure is not meaningful if buried in lengthy, fine print con-
tracts. The seller should be required to ensure that the purchaser is aware
of key options, restrictions, and rights.
Instead of standard terms regulations, the Consumer Restatement
advocates for expanded judicial review of consumer contract terms to
ensure a fair bargain. In order to “insure” such an outcome, § 5 “encour-
ages” the courts to more aggressively use the doctrine of unconscionabil-
ity.
117
This fails to recognize that more and more businesses are inserting
arbitration clauses into their contracts. Although, the doctrine of uncon-
scionability has been used to void unfair arbitration clauses that leave a
consumer without an adequate recourse to seek a remedy,
118
recent
trends
119
do not bode well for consumers. The Supreme Court has re-
emphasized that arbitration is the preferred means of dispute resolution
under the Federal Arbitration Act,
120
while at the same time limiting con-
sumers’ ability to obtain a remedy through arbitration. It has held that
contract clauses waiving the consumer’s right to join class action arbitra-
tion are enforceable.
121
In the end, it is likely to be a very long time, if
and when the Restatement of Consumer Contract Law is adopted, before
courts recognize and use its provisions. There is greater uncertainty if
and how it is likely to impact consumer abuse in the sale of EWSCs. The
Consumer Restatement project, however, does provide options and con-
cepts that could be incorporated into future regulatory initiatives relating
to EWSCs.
e. Lemon Laws
Most states have enacted some form of lemon law; however, the
content of those laws vary. They are most commonly associated with the
sale of motor vehicles, but can also extend to the sales of heavy equip-
ment and electrical appliances.
122
The standard warranty law in the U.S.
www.consumerfinancemonitor.com/2017/06/02/proposed-consumer-contracts-restatement-cri
tiqued-at-ali-annual-meeting.
117
Project Feature: Restatement of the Law, Consumer Contracts, T
HE
ALI A
DVISER
(May 2017), http://www.thealiadviser.org/consumer-contracts.
118
Id.
119
Id.
120
Federal Arbitration Act (FAA), 9 U.S.C. ch. 1, 43 Stat 883, Pub. L. 68-401 (1925)
(“An Act to make valid and enforceable written provisions or agreements for arbitration of
disputes arising out of contracts, maritime transactions, or commerce among the States.”).
121
DIRECTV, Inc. v. Imburgia, 136 S. Ct. 463 (2015) (holding that class action waivers
contained in arbitration agreements are enforceable under the Federal Arbitration Act and can-
not be invalidated on state law grounds).
122
Terence J. Centner & Michael E. Wetzstein, Obligations and Penalties under Lemon
Laws: Automobiles versus Tractors, 20 J. A
GRIC
. & R
ESOURCE
E
CON
. 135, 135–36 (1995).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 26 14-JUN-19 7:19
508
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
only requires the seller to repair or replace defective products.
123
In the
area of “big ticket” items, such as automobiles, the manufacturer-seller
will almost always elect the repair remedy in order to avoid the more
costly remedy of replacement.
124
This causes hardship on the purchaser
and an avenue of abuse for the seller. If a defect proves difficult to rec-
tify, requiring numerous trips for repair or the product continually
presents new types of defects, then the purchaser suffers a great deal of
inconvenience and loses trust in the durability of the product. A seller
may use the repair remedy in bad faith until the warranty period expires
leaving the purchaser without further recourse for subsequent defects. Of
course, this is a scenario where an EWSC would prove desirable. How-
ever, unless the EWSC provides a right to replacement, the purchaser
will continue to experience the same type of inconvenience and harm due
to the need for serial repair. This type of harm is what lemon laws are
intended to alleviate.
But as noted earlier, most products are manufactured to last as long
as the express warranty under the sales contract and the period of cover-
age of an EWSC; otherwise, the ability to generate large revenue streams
through the sale of EWSCs would not be possible. Nonetheless, there are
at least some products that are shoddy, due to faulty assembly, use of
lower quality materials and component parts, which make them “lem-
ons.” The lemon laws preempt the remedial structure of warranty law by
converting the seller’s option of making continuous repairs to a buyer’s
right to a replacement or refund.
125
This type of right should be included
in EWSCs when a product is in constant need of repair during the period
of coverage.
B. EU and Member States
This Section examines a variety of consumer protection laws in the
EU and in different European countries. This includes a review of the
Consumer Sales Directive, Unfair Contract Terms Directive, Consumer
Rights Directive, Unfair Commercial Practices Directive, Austrian Con-
sumer Protection Act, and the German Civil Code.
123
Id.
124
Id.
125
Id. It should be noted that most state lemon laws, as well as the Federal Magnuson-
Moss Act, allow the purchaser to claim the costs of legal fees as damages, which is a rarity in
the American legal fee system.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 27 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
509
1. Relevance of EWSCs in the EU
EWSCs exist in all Member States, although the regulatory ap-
proaches differ at the domestic level.
126
The 2017 Study on the Costs and
Benefits of Extending Certain Rights Under the Consumer Sales and
Guarantees Directive 1999/94/EC (Costs and Benefits Study), for exam-
ple, points out that three Member States—Finland, Latvia and Slove-
nia—take a comparatively strict approach, allowing paid-for extensions
only in the form of insurances, and not as guarantee extensions or
alterations.
127
In 2015, the European Consumer Centres Network (ECC-Net) pub-
lished an evaluation on EWSCs (2015 ECC-Net Report)
128
The 2015
ECC-Net Report discusses whether EWSCs are “worth the money” and
offers some important insights.
129
Spot on- and off-premise tests
130
showed that the marketing and
costs of EWSCs is of practical relevance throughout Europe. In approxi-
mately 60% of the examined online sale cases EWSCs were advertised
or otherwise offered.
131
A second 2015 study report, the “Study on the
Functioning of the Legal and Commercial Guarantees for Consumers in
the EU,” confirmed the importance of the EWSC market, showing that
approximately 75% of the examined products offered online or offline
were offered in combination with EWSCs.
132
126
See ICF, Study on the Costs and Benefits of Extending Certain Rights Under the Con-
sumer Sales and Guarantees Directive 1999/94/EC, at 33 (Mar. 2017), https://publica-
tions.europa.eu/en/publication-detail/-/publication/4d120ad5-deee-11e7-9749-01aa75ed71a1/
language-en.
127
Id.
128
The 2015 ECC-Net Report is arguably the most comprehensive overview of the Euro-
pean EWSC market. See E
UROPEAN
C
ONSUMER
C
TR
. N
ETWORK
, C
OMMERCIAL
W
ARRANTIES
:
A
RE
T
HEY
W
ORTH THE
M
ONEY
? 6 (2015), https://www.europe-consommateurs.eu/fileadmin/
user_upload/eu-consommateurs/PDFs/PDF_EN/REPORT-_GUARANTEE/Garanties_
2014_FINAL.pdf [hereinafter ECC-N
ET
].
129
Id. Overall, the 2015 ECC-Net Report takes a different approach on guarantees than
the vast majority of older European studies do, in the sense that it does not simply follow the
common approach of determining how the Consumer Sales Directive (CSD) has been imple-
mented by the Member States or measuring the CSD regime’s impact on the legal guarantee
market. See, e.g., EC C
ONSUMER
L
AW
C
OMPENDIUM
: T
HE
C
ONSUMER
A
CQUIS AND ITS
T
RANS-
POSITION IN THE
M
EMBER
S
TATES
1–3 (Hans Schulte-N¨olke et al. eds., 2008). It goes one step
further and provides data and feedback on the EWSC market. The 2015 ECC-Net Report is
built upon a field study, comprised of consumer surveys, contacts with sellers, website analy-
ses, case studies, and interviews carried out by the European Consumer Centres (ECCs) across
the EU, Iceland and Norway in late 2014. See ECC-N
ET
, supra note 128, at 6.
130
A “spot test” is a test conducted on the spot to yield immediate results. See ECC-N
ET
,
supra note 128, at 109–18 (details on how spot tests were used by ECC-Net in its 2015 evalua-
tion of EWSCs).
131
ECC-N
ET
, supra note 128, at 50.
132
See I
PSOS ET AL
., E
UROPEAN
C
OMMISSIONN
, C
ONSUMER
M
ARKET
S
TUDY ON THE
F
UNC-
TIONING OF
L
EGAL AND
C
OMMERCIAL
G
UARANTEES FOR
C
ONSUMERS IN THE
EU: E
XECUTIVE
S
UMMARY
3 (2015), https://ec.europa.eu/info/sites/info/files/legal-guarantees-executive-sum
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 28 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
R
R
510
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
The costs of EWSCs rarely reach 10% of the price of the purchased
goods.
133
Relevant data show that a considerable number of consumers
have actual experience with EWSCs. In a survey carried out by ECC
Belgium, 56.1% of the 543 participants stated that they had, at least once,
purchased an EWSC.
134
About one-third of the participants who made
claims or requests on their EWSCs noted that they did not have a posi-
tive experience.
135
Overall, less than one-third considered purchasing an
EWSC in the future.
136
2. Regulatory Landscape of EWSCs in the EU
The generally relevant guarantee framework in the EU and its Mem-
ber States rests on a strict division between legal guarantees on the one
hand and EWSCs on the other. While both types of guarantees aim to
support buyers of non-conforming products in endeavors to enforce their
legal interests, there is a great deal of differentiation between these two
guarantee forms.
137
This is important, particularly because different reg-
ulatory regimes apply to each type.
As explained above, statutory provisions do not mandate the use of
EWSCs. EWSCs cover purchased goods but are conceived via party au-
tonomy either as an addendum to the sales agreement or in the form of a
separate contract, where the seller and the liable party under the EWSC
are independent companies. EU purchasers create the EWSC with differ-
ent parties: the seller of the good, the manufacturer, or a third-party in-
surer. Some of the relevant pan-EU legislation, such as the CSD, do not
consistently cover all three types of sellers of EWSCs.
138
Further, some
EU laws do not distinguish between legal guarantees and EWSCs. The
Unfair Contract Terms Directive
139
and the Unfair Commercial Practices
Directive
140
are two such laws, as discussed later in this Section.
141
mary_en_0.pdf (arriving at the conclusion that “commercial guarantees have become an inte-
gral part of marketing”).
133
See ECC-N
ET
, supra note 128, at 118.
134
Id. at 120.
135
Id.
136
Id.
137
Supra notes 15–21 and accompanying text.
138
See, e.g., Council Directive 1999/44, art. 1, 1999 O.J. (L 171) 12, 14 (EC) [hereinafter
CSD]. CSD is also known as the Consumer Sales and Guarantees Directive, do not consist-
ently cover all three types of sellers of EWSCs. See ICF, supra note 126, at 3.
139
See UCTD, supra note 60, art. 3(2), 3(3).
140
See Directive 2005/29/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 11 May
2005 Concerning Unfair Business-to-Consumer Commercial Practices in the Internal Market
and Amending Council Directive 84/450/EEC, Directives 97/7/EC, 98/27/EC and 2002/65/EC
of the European Parliament and of the Council and Regulation (EC) No 2006/2004 of the
European Parliament and of the Council, 2005 O.J. (L149) 22 (EU) [hereinafter UCPD] (con-
cerning unfair business-to-consumer commercial practices in the internal market).
141
Infra notes 173–83 and accompanying text.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 29 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
R
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
511
Unlike the U.S., the EU has increasingly differentiated consumer
contracts from general contract and commercial law. In particular, since
the 1990s, the EU has intensified efforts to regulate business-to-con-
sumer (B2C) transactions, most notably and initially, with the help of
numerous laws aimed at different areas or issues of the consumer
economy.
142
In the area of consumer guarantees, there are a handful of European
directives that provide a regulatory framework for the B2C market. At
the center of the scheme stands the CSD with its main focus on legal
guarantees. The key aim of the directive is to create a level playing field
for guarantees across the EU and to raise consumer protection standards
in a number of Member States by introducing a minimum period of two
years for legal guarantees.
143
This is accompanied by some additional
consumer protections, such as a partial reversal of the burden of proof
144
and the enunciation of a mandatory catalogue of minimum remedies.
145
The CSD incorporates additional rules for associated-integral guar-
antees or express warranties included in the sale of the product in Article
6 (guarantees). The CSD defines such guarantees as “any undertaking by
a seller or producer to the consumer, given without extra charge, to re-
imburse the price paid or to replace, repair or handle consumer goods in
any way if they do not meet the specifications set out in the guarantee
statement or in the relevant advertising.”
146
Article 6 guarantees have to
fulfill two primary requirements, notice and intelligible language.
147
With this obligation, the European legislature aimed to maximize
the certainty and comprehensibility level with respect to the rights of
142
These directives were part of what is usually called the “consumer acquis,” which is a
group of eight sectoral consumer directives focused on selected consumer issues introduced in
the EU during the end of the 20th century. See EC Consumer Law Compendium, supra note
129, at 1; see also S
TEFAN
W
RBKA
, E
UROPEAN
C
ONSUMER
A
CCESS TO
J
USTICE
R
EVISITED
162
(2015) (identifying the eight directives as “seven substantial law directives and one procedural
law directive”).
143
See CSD, supra note 138, art. 1(1), 5(1) (starting at the time of the delivery of the
goods).
144
See CSD, supra note 138, art. 5(3) (“Unless proved otherwise, any lack of conformity
[with the contract of sale as articulated in Article 2] which becomes apparent within six
months of delivery of the goods shall be presumed to have existed at the time of
delivery . . . .”).
145
See CSD, supra note 138, art. 3 (detailing means of determining the appropriate reme-
dies consumers may have available to them in the case of lack of conformity with the sales
contract as identified in Article 2).
146
See CSD, supra note 138, art. 1 (2)(e) (emphasis added).
147
“The guarantee shall: state that the consumer has legal rights under applicable national
legislation governing the sale of consumer goods and make clear that those rights are not
affected by the guarantee [and] set out in plain intelligible language the contents of the guaran-
tee and the essential particulars necessary for making claims under the guarantee, notably the
duration and territorial scope of the guarantee as well as the name and address of the guaran-
tor.” See CSD, supra note 138, art. 6(2).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 30 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
512
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
buyers.
148
Consumers must be made aware of the fact that the legal guar-
antees are an absolute, mandatory minimum and that Article 6 guarantees
cannot be limited in anyway. In addition, traders who offer Article 6
guarantees must make arrangements to enhance the understanding of
consumers about the content of the guarantee. Article 6 guarantees are
not comparable to what was earlier defined as EWSCs.
149
Paid-for
EWSCs fall outside the scope of Article 6 and the CSD in general.
Member States have implemented the relevant European defaults,
but have rarely exercised their legislative leeway (where granted) to go
beyond the minimum standards of the European directives. Consequen-
tially, most Member States apply a principally unified EWSC regime to
ensure the highest possible level of comprehensibility.
150
Some countries
have increased the level of protections beyond the mandatory minimum
standards provided in the CSD.
151
For example, in implementing the
CSD, some countries opted for a broad approach and introduced a com-
paratively comprehensive provision on consumer guarantees that reads as
follows:
(1) When an entrepreneur undertakes to a consumer to
improve or replace any defective good, to refund the
purchase price or otherwise make good the defect (com-
mercial warranty), he shall also inform the consumer of
the legal warranty imposed on the person handing over
the good and shall point out that such legal warranty
shall not be limited by the commercial warranty. The en-
trepreneur shall be bound by the promises made in the
warranty statement and its content as notified in his
advertising.
(2) The warranty statement shall include the name and
address of the warrantor and, in simple and straightfor-
ward terms, the content of the warranty, including but
not limited to the term and geographical application and
all other information necessary for drawing on the war-
ranty. If the warranted features are not made clear from
the statement, the warrantor shall be liable for the good
to have those features customarily required of it.
148
See CSD, supra note 138, art. 6(2).
149
Supra Part I.A.
150
See Oren Bar-Gill & Omri Ben-Shahar, Regulatory Techniques in Consumer Protec-
tion: A Critique of European Consumer Contract Law, (Coase-Sandor Inst. for Law & Econ.,
Working Paper No. 598, 2012).
151
See id.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 31 14-JUN-19 7:19
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
513
(3) The commercial warranty shall be furnished to the
consumer at his request in writing or by another perma-
nent data carrier that the consumer can make use of.
(4) If the warrantor violates Paragraphs 1 through 3
above, this shall not affect the validity of the commercial
warranty. The warrantor shall furthermore be liable to
the consumer for any loss or damage caused by such
violation.
152
Note that in those broad approaches, the concept of the “commercial
warranty” goes beyond integral guarantee, such as a manufacturer’s war-
ranty or integral guarantees offered by the seller, and encompasses
EWSCs.
153
The law does not merely refer to the manufacturer or seller,
but to the entrepreneur or warrantor in general.
154
As to substantive con-
tent the law is not very detailed but does require that the warrantor honor
its obligations made in the form of advertisements, disclose any geo-
graphic limitations, and clarify the content or scope of the warranty. In
the event of not providing a clear statement, the law provides: “If war-
ranted features are not made clear from the statement, the warrantor shall
be liable for the good to have those features customarily required of it.”
This provision mandates that courts perform a contextual interpretation
of the warranty. Contextualism in this instance refers to an interpretation
not based solely on the words of the warranty, but based upon the reason-
able expectations of the purchaser. These expectations are circumscribed
by what is “customarily required.” Thus, if the EWSC provides a lower
than customary level of protection, then it will be assumed that the
EWSC provides the higher customary level of protection.
For example, Section 443 of the German Civil Code (BGB) stipu-
lates as follows:
(1) Where the seller, the producer or some other third
party enters into obligation, in addition to his statutory
liability for defects, by way of making a declaration or in
relevant advertising that was available prior to the
purchase agreement being concluded or at the time of its
conclusion, such obligation being in particular to reim-
burse the purchase price, to exchange the thing, to repair
it or to provide services in this context should the thing
152
K
ONSUMENTENSCHUTZGESETZ
[KS
CH
G] [C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
L
AW
]
B
UNDESGESETZBLATT
[BGB
L
], No. 140/1979 as amended, § 9b, translation at https://www.
ris.bka.gv.at/Dokument.wxe?Abfrage=erv&Dokumentnummer=ERV_1979_140 (Austria)
[hereinafter KSchG]. The term “commercial warranty” used by the translator is a synonym for
“EWSC.”
153
Id.
154
Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 32 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
514
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
not exhibit the quality or not fulfill other requirements
than those concerning its freedom from defects, in each
case as described in the declaration or in the relevant
advertisement (guarantee), the buyer shall be entitled, in
the case of a guarantee having been given, and notwith-
standing his statutory claims, to the rights under the
guarantee in relation to the person who has given the
guarantee (guarantor).
(2) To the extent that the guarantor gives a guarantee as
to the thing having a specified quality for a specified pe-
riod (guarantee of durability), the presumption will be
that a material defect, which appears during the guaran-
tee period [and] triggers the rights under the
guarantee.
155
Again, as found in the Austrian law, the German BGB Section 443(1)
emphasizes that the scope of an EWSC can be determined not only on
the written form but also by oral declarations, promises, and representa-
tion, as well as relevant advertising prior to the purchase.
156
No such
broad evidential base is found in American law. First, advertisements are
considered to be non-binding in nature.
157
Second, oral representations
before, or contemporaneous to, the signing of the EWSC are merged into
the written form and are barred by the parol evidence rule
158
from being
entered into evidence to contradict the written form. Section 443(2) re-
fers to the EWSC as a guarantee of durability and provides a legal pre-
sumption that any material defect is covered under the guarantee,
whether expressly stated or not.
159
Section 477 of the BGB adds special requirements for consumer
guarantees:
1) A declaration of guarantee (section 443) must be ex-
pressed simply and comprehensibly. It must contain:
1. a reference to the statutory rights of the consumer
and a statement that they are not restricted by the
guarantee, and
2. the contents of the guarantee and all essential in-
formation required for asserting rights under the
155
BGB, supra note 75, at § 443.
156
Id.
157
Professor Farnsworth states that common law courts “show a reluctance, in doubtful
cases, to characterize a proposal as an offer.” See F
ARNSWORTH
, supra note 49, at 237.
158
Parol evidence rule bars the admission of extrinsic evidence (prior dealings, course of
performance, trade usage) to contradict the plain meaning of a written contract intended to be
the final integration of the party’s agreement. See id. at 210; see also id. at 210–29 (explaining
the definition and application of the parol evidence rule).
159
See BGB, supra note 75, § 443(2).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 33 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
515
guarantee, including, without limitation, the dura-
tion and the area of territorial application of the
guarantee protection as well as the name and ad-
dress of the guarantor.
(2) The consumer may demand that the declaration of
guarantee is given to him in text form.
(3) The effectiveness of the duty under the guarantee is
not affected by the fact that one of the above require-
ments is not satisfied.
160
Section 477 makes clear that it is the obligation of the guarantor to pro-
vide the contents and all “essential information required for asserting
rights under the guarantee”
161
in a simple and comprehensible manner.
This language sets the interpretive threshold well above the practice of
obfuscation and hard selling of detailed standard form EWSCs in the
U.S. Also, the Austrian and German approaches have to be understood as
exemplary extensions of CSD Article 6 guarantees in several ways.
162
First, and unlike CSD Article 6, these national frameworks are not lim-
ited to no-cost guarantees, but additionally cover paid-for EWSCs.
163
The 2001 explanatory memorandum accompanying the Austrian amend-
ment to the Austrian Consumer Protection Act (national warranty re-
gime) described this framework as the wish to treat the beneficiaries of
paid-for EWSCs and no-cost EWSCs equally.
164
The explanatory memo-
randum further explains that the regulatory differentiation between these
types of guarantees in which greater protections are provided for non-
paid-for guarantees than are provided for paid-for guarantees is simply
not justifiable.
165
Second, the Austrian and German laws of guarantee show that the
circle of guarantors is wider than under the CSD. Whereas CSD Article 6
explicitly restricts the scope to the “seller or producer” of the respective
product, the Austrian and German laws have provided norms for ex-
160
BGB § 477.
161
Id.
162
Both national solutions are not the exception, but rather the rule. Member States have
widely opted for broader regulations of the EWSC regime at the national level. See, e.g., EC
C
ONSUMER
L
AW
C
OMPENDIUM
, supra note 129 (reporting on the legislative techniques of Eu-
ropean Community Member States).
163
Compare CSD, supra note 138 (focusing on no-cost guarantees), with KS
CH
G, supra
note 152, and BGB, supra note 75, § 477 (additionally covering paid-for EWSCs).
164
422 der Beilagen zu den Stenographischen Protokollen des Nationalrates XXI. GP
(Jan. 22, 2001) 25 (explanatory memorandum accompanying G
EW
¨
AHRLEISTUNGSRECHTS
-
¨
A
NDERUNGSGESETZ
[G
EW
R
¨
A
MENDMENT
AG] [W
ARRANTY
A
CT
] B
UNDESEGESETZBLATT
I
[BGB
L
I] No. 48/2001, as amended, https://www.parlament.gv.at/PAKT/VHG/XXI/I/I_
00422/fname_202157.pdf (Austria)).
165
Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 34 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
516
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
panding the scope to cover third parties (other than the producer).
166
In
this sense the national regimes cover “pseudo” guarantees
167
given by
sellers, as well as “genuine” guarantees
168
given by third parties (manu-
facturers and other third parties including third-party insurers). At the
same time, however, it should be noted that in practice the situation re-
mains complex. German scholars point out that despite the comprehen-
siveness of the German EWSC regime, distinctions continue to be made
with respect to the type of guarantees in a wider sense. This is largely
the case because the provisions do not go beyond “dependent” guaran-
tees,
169
which are guarantees that relate to the contractual conformity
most notably by extending the duration of legal guarantees or broadening
the scope of liable parties to third-party insurers that would finance a
repair or replacement of a defective good. Hence, “independent” guaran-
tees
170
merely cover for accidental damage. These types of guarantees do
not cover contractual non-conformities and therefore there is no right to
repair or replacement costs related to such non-conformity. This distinc-
tion between harm caused by accident and harm caused by non-conform-
ity is the basis for the division between EWSCs and EWSC equivalent
insurances on the one hand and insurances that are to a greater extent
standalone.
171
The standalone-types of third-party insurance have fea-
tures that are different from ordinary guarantee remedies, such as only
making compensation payments instead of repair and replacement.
172
Drawing clear distinctions between the different types of insurance and
associated hybrids proves difficult. In practice, one would have to closely
look at the contractual relationships between the parties and the terms of
the respective guarantee.
Three additional, broader directives add perspective to the regula-
tion of guarantees under EU law, albeit in different ways. The Unfair
Contract Terms Directive (UCTD) was introduced in 1993 with the aim
of establishing a common framework relating to the use of standard con-
¨
166
See Christian Berger, § 443, in B
URGERLICHES
G
ESETZBUCH
: BGB (Rolf St¨urner et al.
¨
eds., 15th ed. 2014) § 443 Recital 8 (German law); Christian Berger, § 477, in B
URGERLICHES
G
ESETZBUCH
: BGB § 477 Recital 1 (Rolf St¨urner et al. eds., 15th ed. 2014); Georg Kathrein &
Thomas Schoditsch, § 9b KSchG, in ABGB K
URZKOMMENTAR
§ 9b KSchG Recital 1 (Helmut
Koziol, Peter Bydlinski & Raimund Bollenberger eds., 4th ed. 2014) (Austrian law); Peter
Apathy, § 9b KSchG, in ABGB P
RAXISKOMMENTAR
-B
AND
5 § 9b KSchG Recital 1 (Georg
Kodek & Michael Schwimann eds., 4th edn. 2014).
167
Apathy, supra note 166, at §9b KSchG, Recital 2 (unechte Garantien).
168
Id. (echte Garantien).
169
Berger, supra note 166, § 443, Recital 9 (unselbst ¨andige Garantien).
170
Id. (selbst¨andige Garantien).
171
Under European nomenclature, extended warranties or service contracts provided by
third parties would be considered an insurance product and not a commercial guarantee. Thus,
EWSC-like is an EWSC issued by a third-party (insurance company). In the U.S., such a
product would be simply known as an EWSC. See supra Part I.A.
172
See infra Part II.C.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 35 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
R
R
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
517
tract forms, terms, and conditions that have a negative impact on con-
sumer interests.
173
The UCTD is remarkably wide in its application and,
in principle, does not necessitate distinguishing between different guar-
antee and insurance instruments.
174
Most notably, the UCTD covers both
third-party agreement types of insurance and genuine insurance.
175
However, the impact of the UCTD and its national implementations
as a means of regulating EWSCs is not likely to be significant, even if
future findings of planned obsolescence show that such regulation is
needed. EWSCs’ failure to offer durations long enough to cover obsoles-
cence-related repairs may not meet the threshold of unfairness required
by the UCTD. The perceived “unfairness” would not be of a nature that
would cause “a significant imbalance in the parties’ rights and obliga-
tions arising under the contract, to the detriment of the consumer.”
176
The Annex of UCTD lists “indicative and non-exhaustive”
177
unfair
terms. Cases of insufficiently long guarantee periods are not covered.
Overall, it remains highly questionable and uncertain whether the dura-
tion of EWSCs would constitute unfairness, particularly, in cases where
the offeror of the guarantee had no knowledge about the expectable lifes-
pan of the product. Also, since EWSCs provide an additional period of
protection, even for a short period of time, beyond the mandatory dura-
tion of legal guarantees they make a weak case for a party claiming un-
fairness under the UCTD.
178
Roughly ten years after the introduction of the UCTD, the EU legis-
lature enacted the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive (UCPD).
179
The UCPD amended a number of older initiatives on banning socially
and widely unacceptable business strategies that had been applied to
maximize profits.
180
The directive includes a number of provisions that
prohibit unfair commercial practices.
181
Most notably, the broadly de-
173
See UCTD, supra note 60.
174
See O
FFICE OF
F
AIR
T
RADING
(OFT), U
NFAIR
C
ONTRACT
T
ERMS
G
UIDANCE
: G
UI-
DANCE FOR THE
U
NFAIR
T
ERMS IN
C
ONSUMER
C
ONTRACTS
R
EGULATIONS
1999 35–36, 50–51
(Sept. 2008), https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/at
tachment_data/file/284426/oft311.pdf.
175
Id.
176
See UCTD, supra note 60, art. 3(1), at 31.
177
UCTD, supra note 60, art. 3(3), at 31.
178
One can justifiably argue that such clauses relate to the main subject matter of the
guarantee contract and hence, in principle, are exempted by the UCTD, as explained in its
recitals as follows: “[F]or the purposes of this Directive, assessment of unfair character shall
not be made of terms which describe the main subject matter of the contract nor the quality/
price ratio of the goods or services supplied.” Id. at 30.
179
See UCPD, supra note 140.
180
See UCPD, supra note 140; see also Jana Valant, European Parliamentary Research
Serv., Application of the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive: Overview of the Commis-
sion’s May 2016 Guidance Document, at 4 (Jan. 2017).
181
See Valant, supra note 180.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 36 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
R
R
R
518
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
fined catalogue of UCPD Article 5 includes misleading and aggressive
business practices.
182
Compared with the UCTD, the UCPD might offer
a more suitable approach towards banning “abusive” sale of EWSCs,
particularly in the context of planned obsolescence.
183
Notably, the
UCPD Article 5(2)(a) requires the applied commercial practices be “con-
trary to the requirements of professional diligence” to be considered un-
fair in the sense of the directive. Hence, here as well, one would have to
identify a culpability element to allow for remediation under the law.
In an attempt to standardize the fragmented nature of older con-
sumer directives, the 2011 Consumer Rights Directive (CRD; also
known as the Directive on Consumer Rights) repealed two earlier direc-
tives on distance and doorstep selling and added a Member State obliga-
tion to inform the EU Commission of stricter national legislation that is
passed as consequence of the legislative leeway provided by the UCTD
and CSD. In the present context, particularly noteworthy are the two in-
formation catalogues of the CRD—one for distance and off-premises
B2C transactions (CRD Article 6(1)) and one for B2C transactions other
than distance and off-premises contracts (CRD Article 5(1)).
184
With re-
spect to guarantees, the information obligations are similar in both
groups. Traders have to inform consumers “in a clear and comprehensi-
ble manner” about “the existence of a legal guarantee of conformity for
goods,” as well as where applicable, “the existence and the conditions of
. . . commercial guarantees.”
185
The CRD and its possible application to
EWSCs will be further discussed in the next Part.
186
C. Regulatory Insufficiencies Related to EWSCs in the EU and EU
Member States
Though some national schemes have gone beyond the minimum re-
quirements enshrined in EU laws,
187
there is a need for further ancillary
regulations, especially due to challenges posed by planned obsolescence
to be discussed in Part III.
188
The 2015 ECC-Net Report commences with a summary of some of
the positive and negative characteristics of EWSCs.
189
First, EWSCs of-
fer some additional protections that go beyond legal guarantees.
190
Most
182
See UCPD, supra note 140, at 27.
183
See G
ERAINT
H
OWELLS
& S
TEPHEN
W
EATHERILL
, C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
L
AW
210
(2d ed. 2005) and text accompanying note 197.
184
CRD, supra note 21, at 74–76.
185
CRD, supra note 21, arts. 5(1)(e), 6(1)(l) & 6(1)(m), at 74–76.
186
See infra Part IV.B.0 (Austrian and German laws).
187
See observations in supra Part III.B.2.
188
ECC-N
ET
, supra note 128; I
PSOS ET AL
., supra note 132.
189
See ECC-N
ET
, supra note 128, at 7.
190
Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 37 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
519
notably these include longer guarantee periods, additionally liable par-
ties, or additional coverage, such as repair at home services or compensa-
tion for damages due to accident.
191
In the context of the present analysis on EWSCs and planned obso-
lescence, the incremental length of the extended duration provided by
EWSCs becomes the key issue. The length of guarantee periods, given
engineered product lifetimes, becomes central to the assessment of
whether guarantees are really worth the money charged or are cases of
overreaching. The findings revealed in the 2015 ECC-Net Report on the
average durations of EWSCs (related to the sale of photo cameras, wash-
ing machines and televisions) showed that in a significant number of
cases, the duration of the advertised EWSCs actually added little, if any,
additional benefits to the consumer.
192
In 95 of the 173 examined cases
(55%) the EWSC offered did not exceed the two-year period of legal
guarantees, which is the minimum duration required by CSD Article
5(1).
193
The 2015 ECC-Net Report further shows that in cases where
extensions were offered, the vast majority did not go beyond a total of
five years (i.e. an extension of three years past the two years provided by
legal guarantees).
194
The 2015 Market Study found a slightly higher percentage where
EWSCs offered longer guarantee durations than legally required; never-
theless, that study found that approximately one-third of the examined
paid-for EWSCs did not include any extension of duration of
coverage.
195
Particularly in cases where longer product lifetimes are justifiably
expected, the true extra benefits remain questionable.
196
Geraint Howells
and Stephen Weatherill’s review of the 2015 Market Study on the EWSC
market concluded that:
In theory this two tier guarantee level—normal [i.e. le-
gal] and extended [i.e. commercial] guarantee—should
be applauded as it allows consumers to select the level of
cover desired, but does not force all consumers to pay
for long-term guarantees. The danger is that the addi-
191
Id. at 7, 50–51.
192
Id. at 62–63.
193
Id. at 116.
194
Id.
195
Market Study, supra note 1, at 92.
196
ECC-N
ET
, supra note 128, at 116–17. Just see the example of washing machines.
Among the tested product categories, washing machines showed the highest percentage of
extended warranties. But even here, the offered durations stayed largely behind the standard
lifetimes generally expected or examined. See id. at 117. A similar, but slightly more critical
way is proposed by Petra Kirchhoff, Garantie-Vertr¨age—Teurer Extraschutz, FAZ (May 11,
2009), www.faz.net/aktuell/rhein-main/wirtschaft/garantie-vertraege-teurer-extraschutz-
1799624.html.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 38 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
R
R
R
520
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
tional cover is both overpriced and provides only what
consumers had come to expect under the normal
guarantee.
197
It should be noted that in a considerable number of jurisdictions, such as
Sweden, Iceland, Norway, Ireland, the U.K., the Netherlands and Fin-
land, the legally required duration of legal guarantees exceeds the CSD
model of two years from delivery.
198
These extended guarantee durations
are on the surface pro-consumer, but some of the unintended negative
consequences include less coverage derived from paid-for EWSCs and
higher prices.
Overall the 2015 ECC-Net Report is inconclusive as to the benefit
of EWSCs relative to costs.
199
Thus, more study is needed on issues ex-
posed by the Report. First, the European EWSC industry is characterized
by a significant degree of non-transparency and often fails to provide
appropriate, effective consumer information. This is despite the mandates
in the CSD
200
and CRD
201
that require the disclosure of consumer infor-
mation. As outlined above, Article CSD 6(2) obliges the offeror of
EWSCs to:
state that the consumer has legal rights under applicable
national legislation governing the sale of consumer
goods and [to] make clear that those rights are not af-
fected by the guarantee [and to] set out in plain intelligi-
ble language the contents of the guarantee and the
essential particulars necessary for making claims under
the guarantee, notably the duration and territorial scope
of the guarantee as well as the name and address of the
guarantor.
202
Comparable provisions can be found in the CRD, most notably in Article
5(1)(e) (for contracts other than distance or off-premises contracts) and
in Article 6(1)(m) (for distance and off-premises contracts). Moreover,
197
G
ERAINT
H
OWELLS
& S
TEPHEN
W
EATHERILL
, C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
L
AW
210 (2d
ed. 2005).
198
ECC-N
ET
, supra note 128, at 96. The duration of the legal guarantee provided under
national legislation is three years in Sweden; five years in Iceland, Norway, and Scotland; and
six years in Ireland, England, Wales and Northern Ireland. Id. In Finland and the Netherlands,
the duration is more flexible and takes the expected lifetime of the product into consideration
(with a minimum duration of two years). Id. For details and references to domestic legislation
on these and other European schemes, see ICF, supra note 126, at 13–16.
199
ECC-Net, supra note 128, at 73–83.
200
See CSD, supra note 138, art. 6(2).
201
See CRD, supra note 21, art. 26.
202
See CSD, supra note 138, art. 6(2).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 39 14-JUN-19 7:19
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
521
many Member States have opted for an even stricter approach that covers
scenarios not encompassed by the pan-EU instruments.
203
Despite these legal requirements, the EWSC industry may either
lack knowledge of the regulatory standards or simply fail to fully com-
ply; or, more importantly, regulators may have been lax in enforcing the
disclosure requirements. In response to non-enforcement or non-compli-
ance issues, Article 9 of the 2014 Consumer Protection Cooperation Reg-
ulation (CPC Regulation) encourages national consumer protection
authorities to participate in market surveillance and enforcement activi-
ties, commonly referred to as “sweeps.”
204
The EU has now codified the
need for sweeps in Article 29 of a new CPC Regulation, which takes
effect on January 17, 2020.
205
In the 2014 Sweep on Guarantees in the
Electronic Goods Sector (2014 Guarantee Sweep), consumer protection
authorities in twenty-six Member States
206
surveyed a substantial num-
ber of websites with Iceland and Norway screening more than 400 web-
sites on which EWSCs were offered on electronic goods.
207
The websites
were graded on their conformity with the information and disclosure re-
quirements of pertinent EU legislation.
208
Irregularities were found in
more than half of the cases.
209
The most common issues concerned mis-
leading information with respect to the duration or geographical scope of
the advertised EWSCs, the identity (including the name and address) of
the guarantor,
210
and a lack of reference to mandatory legal guaran-
tees.
211
The 2014 Guarantee Sweep confirmed that consumers were not
provided sufficient information to make informed decisions. Though, the
203
See supra Part III.B.2.
204
Regulation (EC) No 2006/2004 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 27
October 2004 on Cooperation Between National Authorities Responsible for the Enforcement
of Consumer Protection Laws (the Regulation on Consumer Protection Cooperation), 2004
O.J. (L 364) 1, 6.
205
Regulation (EU) No 2017/2394 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 12
December 2017 on Cooperation Between National Authorities Responsible for the Enforce-
ment of Consumer Protection Laws and Repealing Regulation (EC) No 2006/2004, 2017 O.J.
(L 345) 1, 20.
206
See Better Application of EU Guarantees in Online Shopping of Electronics, E
UR
.
C
ONSUMER
C
TR
. A
USTRIA
(June 1, 2015), http://europakonsument.at/en/page/better-applica-
tion-eu-guarantees-online-shopping-electronics. Austria and Poland did not take part in the
sweep. Id.
207
See Sweeps, E
UR
. C
OMMISSION
, https://ec.europa.eu/info/live-work-travel-eu/consum
ers/enforcement-consumer-protection/sweeps_en.
208
Id.
209
Id.
210
See Commission Staff Working Document, Impact Assessment, Accompanying the
Document Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on Coop-
eration Between National Authorities Responsible for the Enforcement of Consumer Protec-
tion Laws, at 5, COM (2016) 283 final (May 25, 2016) (both occurred in 20% of the examined
cases) (both occurred in 20% of the examined cases).
211
Id. (both occurred in 40% of the examined cases).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 40 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
R
R
R
522
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
sweep did lead to a significant improvement as authorities intervened to
increase compliance levels from 46% to 82%.
212
Another key finding is the inconsistency of the regulatory schemes
between EWSCs sold by manufacturers and retailers versus those sold by
third-party insurers. The regulatory situation with respect to sellers and
producers appears widely coherent. In both cases the requirements, par-
ticularly as introduced by the CSD and CRD and their national imple-
mentations, apply equally to EWSCs sold by manufacturer-retailers. In
contracts, the regulation relating to EWSCs offered by third-party insur-
ers remains complex and incoherent.
213
In this context, the 2015 ECC-
Net Report looks at the differences between EWSC-like insurances and
genuine insurances given that different legal frameworks apply to
them.
214
EWSC-like insurances (particularly if provided for by national
legislation) might be treated equally to ordinary EWSCs. Genuine insur-
ances, on the other hand, are explicitly exempted from the applicability
of the CRD
215
and fall within the domain of sectoral legislation, most
notably the 2002 Distance Marketing of Consumer Financial Services
Directive
216
and the 2009 Solvency II Directive (Solvency II).
217
The ECC-Net and other studies indicate that the complexity of the
regulatory framework has practical relevance. The 2015 ECC-Net Re-
port, for example, notes that at least 13% of the evaluated EWSCs con-
cerned third-party stakeholders that offered either commercial guarantees
or genuine insurances.
218
The 2015 Market Study found that 30% of the
212
See Sweeps, supra note 207.
213
Recall already the narrow definition of EWSCs used by the CRD. CRD Article 2(14)
on the definition of EWSCs principally excludes agreements with third parties (other than
manufacturers) from the scope of application. See CRD, supra note 21, at 73. With respect to
“genuine” insurances see further the exclusion by Article 3(d) CRD. Id. at 73–74. A definition
of financial services is found in Article 2(12) CRD: “any service of a banking, credit, insur-
ance, personal pension, investment or payment nature.” Id. at 73 (emphasis added).
214
See ECC-N
ET
, supra note 128, at 81–82.
215
See CRD, supra note 21, arts. 2(12), 3(3)(d), at 73–74.
216
Directive 2002/65/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 23 September
2002 Concerning the Distance Marketing of Consumer Financial Services and Amending
Council Directive 90/619/EEC and Directives 97/7/EC and 98/27/EC, 2002 O.J. (L 271) 16;
see CRD, supra note 21, at 68 (“Member States should . . . draw inspiration from existing
Union legislation when legislating in areas not regulated at Union level, in such a way that a
level playing field for all consumers and all contracts relating to financial services is
ensured.”).
217
Directive 2009/138/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 25 Novem-
ber 2009 on the Taking-up and Pursuit of the Business of Insurance and Reinsurance (Sol-
vency II), 2009 O.J. (L 335) 1 [hereinafter Solvency II]. Solvency II broadly aligns national
insurance frameworks in the EU. For the sake of focusing on the key topics EWSCs and
planned obsolescence, it shall suffice to highlight that Articles 183–86 of Solvency II because
they contain substantive rules on the content of insurance contracts. Id. at 74–76. They cover
questions relating to, for example, pre-contractual information, withdrawal rights and cooling-
off periods and the monitoring of unfair contract terms. Id.
218
ECC-N
ET
, supra note 128, at 113.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 41 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
523
screened guarantee services were insurance-based.
219
A number of im-
portant, more generally applicable regulatory frameworks, such as the
UCTD and UCPD could apply regardless of the design of the guarantee
product. But practical issues might arise when trying to determine
whether the concrete package constitutes an EWSC-like insurance that
would fall under the regulatory regime for EWSCs or genuine insurance
that would have to be treated differently. This difficulty in distinguishing
EWSC and genuine insurance is discussed in the 2015 ECC-Net Report:
“Given the content of some commercial warranties and the organizations
providing them, especially if they are not free, it is tempting to draw a
parallel with insurance. It is an open question whether some commercial
warranties are not actually insurance policies. Some are even sold as
such.”
220
Taking the complexity of the instruments and the possible lack
of legal knowledge of the average buyer and seller, it is imperative that
rules on EWSC-like insurances are aligned with those that apply to genu-
ine insurances to avoid unnecessary confusion.
221
By aligning or unify-
ing the regulatory frameworks, consumers will be better equipped to
make informed decisions in purchasing EWSCs and EWSC-like service
packages that include genuine insurances.
III. P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
EWSC
S
The issue in the EWSC industry is not the long-term durability of
the product, but the durability of the product during the period of the
EWSC. Is the seller of the contract a gambler betting that the premium or
219
Market Study, supra note 1, at 92.
220
ECC-N
ET
, supra note 128, at 81. For a practical example, see “Amazon Protect” ad-
vertised on Amazon Germany for a wide range of electronic goods. See Amazon Protect Prod-
ucts,
AMAZON
.
DE
, https://www.amazon.de (enter “amazon protect” into search bar). Offered
and sold by a third-party insurer—at the time of writing this Article: London General Insur-
ance Company Limited—it comes in different package principally distinguishing between
time-wise extensions—“extra guarantees” (Extra-Garantie)—on the one hand and additional
cover—“device protection” (Ger¨ateschutz)—on the other. See id. Purchasers would have to
contact Amazon service centers. The services offered would financially be covered by the
third-party insurer, who himself operates pursuant to agreements with Amazon. See id. Are
these products genuine insurances that fall outside the regulatory scope of the CRD or could
they—per analogy—be considered as EWSC like insurances, or as “ancillary contracts” in the
sense of Article 2(15) CRD, supra note 21, at 73. Case-law has yet to settle this issue.
221
One should additionally note the likely relevance of Articles 2(15) and 15 CRD on
ancillary contracts that could introduce a third category. See CRD, supra note 21, at 73, 80.
Article 2(15) CRD defines ancillary contracts as “contract[s] by which the consumer ac-
quires . . . services related to a distance contract or an off-premises contract and where . . .
those services are provided by the trader or by a third party on the basis of an arrangement
between that third party and the trader.” Id. at 73. With respect to this third group (and under
the condition that the contract is not excluded by Article 3(d) CRD), alternative regulations
come into play, most notably Article 15 CRD on the effect of withdrawals from the main
contract and Article 15 of the Consumer credit agreements directive to which Article 15(1)
CRD refers. Id. at 80.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 42 14-JUN-19 7:19
524
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
price paid for the EWSC will exceed the cost of any claims? This seem-
ing gamble is a sure win for the seller. In the ad hoc case, the outlay of
costs of repair may be larger than the price paid for the EWSC, but over
a large quantity of cases, the surplus generated in favor of the seller
(price minus costs or repair) is always substantial. The certainty of gener-
ating great profits is due to the planned or engineered obsolescence of a
product extending beyond the term of the EWSC. Putting it in more sin-
ister terms, the manufacturer plans and produces its products to fail, in
order to generate future revenues related to the products’ lack of durabil-
ity, but beyond the time of the EWSC. A side benefit to the manufacturer
is any repairs require the purchase of manufacturer-specific replacement
parts. This fact lowers the costs in the probability calculation.
222
The
benefits to the manufacturer from planned obsolescence continue since
the sale replacement after the expiration of the EWSC provides an addi-
tional source of revenue. The actual level of intentionality or culpability
is found in the files of the manufacturers; especially those that sell
EWSCs.
The problem with planned obsolescence is that the purchaser is no
longer able to use price as a surrogate for quality or, more minimally, for
the durability of products. Planned obsolescence, generally an industry-
wide phenomenon, often results in the reduction of durability (less than
is achievable using state of the art design and materials) across product
categories and brands within a given category of products. This dimin-
ishment of the state of art is motivated by the manufacturers seeking to
increase future sales or repairs.
223
This industry-wide manipulation of
product quality produces a collusion or antitrust effect by lowering com-
petition in the area of durability, as high-end (brand-related) and high-
priced products are manufactured with lower-grade or less durable
materials.
A. United States
The regulation of EWSCs can take two forms. First, existing con-
tract law principles can be applied to police abusive practices in the sale
of EWSCs. Second, federal and state governments could enactment new
222
The price of the EWSC is based upon the seller’s probability estimate of the cost of
future claims. The probability calculation is the mathematical side of what has been called
planned obsolescence. From the manufacturer-provider perspective of EWSC: Price (-)
probability of claim X average costs of claim = profits. The part of the calculation that states:
“probability of claim X average costs of claim” is based upon the planned obsolescence deter-
mined by the manufacturer.
223
State of the art may be related to different characteristics of a product. For example, an
appliance may reflect, or not reflect, various states of art—technological state of the art (the
things the appliance can do); quality or durability state of the art, energy efficiency state of the
art, and environmental state of the art.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 43 14-JUN-19 7:19
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
525
laws or regulations targeted at the EWSC industry. Unfortunately, unlike
some of the initiatives taken in Europe, there has been little interest in
such oversight in the U.S.
1. Contract Law’s Response to Planned Obsolescence
The U.S. does not have a separate, holistic consumer sales or con-
tract law regime. Consumers are protected by implied warranties, but
they are easily disclaimable.
224
A gap in this piecemeal regulatory net-
work has been demonstrated by the evolution of the EWSC industry,
which remains largely unregulated.
225
However, tying of planned obso-
lescence to the duration of EWSCs could theoretically make the EWSC
part and parcel with the sale of goods. This would allow EWSCs to be
captured by the general principles of Articles 1 and 2 of the UCC.
226
The
general principles, whether taken from the UCC or the common law—
including unconscionability, good faith and fair dealing, misrepresenta-
tion, duress, and undue influence—are inherently malleable creatures.
However, that the courts have neither utilized these principles to
monitor the EWC industry nor have the developed specialized rules to
regulate EWSCs. This is unfortunate for two reasons. First, the principles
of unconscionability and good faith could easily be applied to the EWSC
scenario. There is both strong evidence of procedural unconscionability
(EWSCs are almost always sold to consumers; high pressure sales tac-
tics; contracts of adhesion or standard forms; no representation by a
lawyer; severe informational asymmetries) and substantive unconsciona-
bility (exorbitant price of product). Second, the courts have developed
specialized rules to monitor other troublesome contract clauses.
227
Thus,
there are established precedents where the courts have escaped the gravi-
tational pull of freedom of contract to develop rules to protect the weaker
party from the stronger party; such rules should be developed for
EWSCs. These fairness-based tendencies have always existed in the
common law dating back hundreds of years with equitable principles
continuing to influence the law and judicial discretion in the name of
224
U.C.C. § 2-316.
225
See Vehicle Service Contract Industry: How Consumers Lost Millions of Dollars, B
ET-
TER
B
US
. B
UREAU
, http://stlouis.bbb.org/storage/142/documents/vehicleservicecontract-
study2011.pdf (last updated Feb. 18, 2019); see also David Bakke, 6 Reasons Why You Should
Never Purchase an Extended Warranty, U.S. N
EWS
& W
ORLD
R
EP
. (Apr. 24, 2012), http://
money.usnews.com/money/blogs/my-money/2012/04/24/6-reasons-why-you-should-never-
purchase-an-extended-warranty (explaining that warranties are not cost-effective; necessity of
repairs is rare).
226
See Arthur Leff, Contract as Thing, 19 A
M
. U. L. R
EV
. 131, 151 (1970).
227
Examples of such clauses, many created in the common law and later codified by the
U.C.C., real estate law, and so forth, include: covenants not-to-compete, liquidated damages or
penalty clauses, attorney fee clauses, anti-assignment clauses in commercial leases, and limita-
tion of damages and limitation of remedies clauses. See, e.g., U.C.C. § 2-718.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 44 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
526
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
justice.
228
But, courts have refused to see the abusive nature of EWSCs
and have fully enforced them.
2. Regulatory and Judicial Responses
Even though the steps toward regulation in Europe are tentative or
first steps, the regulatory response in the United States has been non-
existent. Information on durability or reliability of automobiles and other
products are readily available online, but federal and state governments
have not intervened to regulate the sale of overpriced EWSCs. Further-
more, the courts have been reluctant to use existing constructs, such as
price gouging statutes
229
or the doctrine of unconscionability
230
to curb
excesses in this industry.
231
The only significant case involving planned obsolescence is Tatum
v. Chrysler Group,
232
which involved a class action suit against Chrysler
in the sale of the Dodge Journey crossover vehicle. The plaintiff alleges
that the brakes on the vehicle required frequent and costly repairs.
Chrysler’s “advertisements, which touted the Journey as safe, durable
and reliable.”
233
Chrysler claimed that: “the brakes routinely outlasted
their sales warranty, and that the advertising was not intended to create a
literal representation, but was merely puffery.”
234
A stronger case of mis-
representation would be available under most European advertising laws,
which see such statements as factual in nature. The court rationalizes that
228
See T. L
EIGH
A
NENSON
, J
UDGING
E
QUITY
: T
HE
F
USION OF
U
NCLEAN
H
ANDS
1–4
(forthcoming 2019); L
ARRY
A. D
I
M
ATTEO
, E
QUITABLE
L
AW OF
C
ONTRACTS
: S
TANDARDS AND
P
RINCIPLES
xii (2001).
229
Price gouging statutes are targeted to the overcharging for services and goods due to
natural disasters or emergencies. F
LA
. S
TAT
. § 501.160 (2005). “Florida’s law prohibits the
unconscionable pricing of commodities during a state of emergency. It is prima facie evidence
that a price is unconscionable.” Edward J. Page & Min K. Cho, Price Gouging 101: A Call to
Florida Lawmakers to Perfect Florida’s Price Gouging Law, 80 F
LA
. B
AR
J. 49, 49 (2006).
230
See U.C.C. § 2-302 (unconscionability). The hard selling of EWSCs meets the two
requirements for a claim of unconscionability: procedural unconscionability (high-pressure
selling tactics, no legal representation, unsophisticated purchasers, lack of full disclosure of
clear information) and substantive unconscionability (highly inflated prices), but courts have
not seen as such, preferring to view EWSCs as products of freedom of contract and fair bar-
gaining. See infra discussion accompanying notes 231–42.
231
A Lexis search of cases using the phrase “planned obsolescence” uncovered only six-
teen federal and state cases and only two were relevant to the sale of durable goods. See search
results, L
EXIS
N
EXIS
, https://advance.lexis.com (search “planned obsolescence”); see e.g.,
Tatum v. Chrysler Group LLC, No. 10-4269, 2011 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 32362, at *1 (D.N.J.,
Mar. 28, 2011).
232
Tatum, 2011 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 32362. Another case in which planned obsolescence
was discussed in dissent is not relevant to the current analysis because it involved the assess-
ment of property; further, this case involved an unpublished opinion and under Michigan Court
of Appeals Rules, has no precedential value. See Danse Corp. v. City of Madison Heights, No.
215486, 2001 Mich. App. LEXIS 1058, at *1 (Ct. App. Mar. 23, 2001).
233
See Tatum, 2011 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 32362, at *2.
234
Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 45 14-JUN-19 7:19
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
527
the statement of products’ durability and reliability is not a misrepresen-
tation by placing the failure of the braking system in the context of the
automobile as a whole. Since it is a single component of many in the
vehicle, then braking failure does not contradict the claim of durability
and reliability.
235
Unfortunately, the court granted summary judgement determining
that there was not a sufficient factual record to decide the case on its
merits. However, in dictum, the court addressed the issue of planned
obsolescence as the basis for a claim, but dismissed the idea out of hand:
“Planned obsolescence, either deliberately or accidentally engineered, is
not actionable, and if the brakes outlasted their sales warranty even by a
day or a mile, there would be nothing rising to the level of a design flaw
for Defendants to warn of.”
236
Thus, the court equates planned obsoles-
cence with the express warranty: as long as the product works properly
during the period of the warranty, then planned obsolescence that results
in failures soon after the expiration of the warranty is not actionable. The
court goes further by reasoning that there is no claim in products liability
for defects of design since there is no such patent defect if the product
lasts through the warranty period. This is an unusually narrow interpreta-
tion of products liability.
The court reasoned that two factors weighed against the vehicle
owners’ claim. First, “that the complaint alleges nothing more than dis-
appointed consumer expectations, which may well turn out to be cor-
rect.”
237
Second, the “Court [wa]s struck, however, by the apparent fact
that none of the cars detailed in the complaint save for one, seem to have
suffered brake failure until after the one year or 12,000 mile sales war-
ranty had expired.”
238
The court further “note[d] that if the sales war-
ranty covered the Journey’s brakes up to 12,000 miles, and the brakes
routinely failed at 12,001 miles, Chrysler would have had no obligation
to repair them.”
239
The court rejected the idea that reasonable expecta-
tions of the purchasers could be used to sustain a claim of products liabil-
ity, misrepresentation, or unconscionability.
235
As to the claims of misrepresentation durability and reliability in Chrysler’s advertise-
ments, the court suggests that “to the extent that any warranty of reliability and durability
could be teased from the advertising, durability and reliability may be based on multiple fac-
tors, not just one element of the car, albeit a vitally important one. Absent specific claims as to
the braking system, Defendant’s general advertising was puffery [hyperbole] as that is under-
stood in the law.” Id. at *13–14.
236
Id. at *10.
237
Tatum, 2011 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 32362, at *8. Again, the court did not rule that this was
in fact true, but its phraseology indicates that it is likely to be true once a full factual record is
produced during the trial. Id.
238
Id.
239
Id. at *9.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 46 14-JUN-19 7:19
528
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
The court then referred to the case of Abraham v. Volkswagen of
America, Inc.
240
decided by the Second Circuit for the following
proposition:
The Abraham Court concluded “virtually all product
failures discovered in automobiles after expiration of the
warranty can be attributed to a ‘latent defect’ that existed
at the time of sale or during the term of the warranty. All
parts will wear out sooner or later and thus have a lim-
ited effective life. Manufacturers always have knowl-
edge regarding the effective life of particular parts and
the likelihood of their failing within a particular period
of time. Such knowledge is easily demonstrated by the
fact that manufacturers must predict rates of failure of
particular parts in order to price warranties and thus can
always be said to ‘know’ that many parts will fail after
the warranty period has expired. A rule that would make
failure of a part actionable based on such ‘knowledge’
would render meaningless time/mileage limitations in
warranty coverage.”
241
The Abraham Court saw the warranty as the only protection owed to the
purchaser. The use of planned obsolescence to ensure failures soon after
the expiration of the warranty period was not seen as anything sinister
but is viewed simply as a business model. The court rejected the owners’
claim of reasonable expectations that the brakes would last beyond the
warranty period. The owners claim that “the size of the brakes compared
to the weight of the car cause the brake pads and rotors to wear out
prematurely “after under 20,000 miles, rather than the 40,000 which
would normally be expected” begs the questions who might have had
those expectations, and on what were they based? If, as Defendant sug-
gests, they are nothing more than consumer expectations and not based
on representations by Chrysler there is nothing actionable.”
242
Again,
this is an affirmation that the use of planned obsolescence to set warran-
ties and escape liability is a perfectly acceptable business practice.
B. The EU and Member States
This section analyzes a number of studies and reports authorized by
institutions of the EU. It then outlines selected national initiatives and
implementations in Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Italy, the Nether-
lands, and Germany.
240
795 F.2d 238 (2d Cir. 1986).
241
Tatum, 2011 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 32362, at *9–10 (quoting Abraham, 795 F.2d at 250
(2d Cir. 1986)).
242
Id. at *11–12.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 47 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
529
1. Legal Development at the EU level
In the 20th century, the phenomenon of planned obsolescence did
not attract significant attention among EU policy-makers. The first, indi-
rect references date back to the start of the new millennium, when envi-
ronmental directives and regulations addressed the issue of reducing
waste in general. Examples include the Waste Electrical and Electronic
Equipment Directive
243
and the Waste Framework Directive.
244
Others,
such as the Ecodesign Directive
245
and the Energy Labelling Directive
246
aimed to provide consumers with information on ecologically relevant
information to allow for an informed decision-making by buyers inter-
ested in purchasing eco-friendly products.
Recently, there has been some movement by a number of stakehold-
ers to recognize a link between obsolescence and legal guarantees, as
well as EWSCs. In 2011, the European Parliament held a forum for an
exchange of views on the sustainability of products. The European Com-
mission was asked to provide answers to a series of Parliamentary ques-
tions concerning planned obsolescence and existing EU law. In this
context the Commission expressed the opinion that planned obsolescence
had become a substantial problem. To accommodate the quest for more
sustainable and resource efficient production, the Commission pointed
out three legal instruments that might be used to regulate product dura-
tion: competition law,
247
the UCPD,
248
and the CSD.
249
Subsequently, the European Economic and Social Committee
(EESC) adopted an opinion on planned obsolescence.
250
The EESC re-
ferred to planned obsolescence broadly as “a form of industrial produc-
243
See Directive 2002/96/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 27 Janu-
ary 2003 on the Waste Electrical and Electronic Equipment (WEEE), 2003 O.J. (L 37) 24.
244
See Directive 2008/98/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 19 No-
vember 2008 on Waste and Repealing Certain Directives, 2008 O.J. (L 312) 3.
245
See Directive 2009/125/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 21 Octo-
ber 2009 Establishing a Framework for the Setting of Ecodesign Requirements for Energy-
Related Products, 2009 O.J. (L 285) 10.
246
See Directive 2010/30/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 19 May
2010 on the Indication by Labelling and Standard Product Information of the Consumption of
Energy and Other Resources by Energy-related Products, 2010 O.J. (L 153) 1, 2.
247
See supra notes 24–25 and accompanying text (describing the Phoebus Cartel); Janez
Poto`enik (European Commissioner for the Environment), Written Questions: E-001284/11, E-
002875/11, E-004273/11, E
UROPEAN
P
ARLIAMENT
(July 8, 2011), http://www.europarl.europa.
eu/sides/getAllAnswers.do?reference=E-2011-001284&language=EN. The Commission sug-
gests that—under the assumption that culpable behavior is constituted—“the fact that a trader
does not inform the consumer when a product has been designed to have a limited lifetime
could be considered as an unfair commercial practice.” Id.
248
See UCPD, supra note 140.
249
See CSD, supra note 138.
250
See generally Opinion of the European Economic and Social Committee and the Com-
mittee on “Towards More Sustainable Consumption: Industrial Product Lifetimes and Restor-
ing Trust Through Consumer Information,2013 O.J. (CCMI 112) 1.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 48 14-JUN-19 7:19
530
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
tion that relies on a minimum renewal rate for its products,” leading to
consumer abuse.
251
The committee highlighted different advantages of
sustainable production, ranging from positive influences on the environ-
ment to greater economic innovation.
252
With respect to guarantees, the
EESC suggested an enhanced system to “curb . . . out the most flagrant
cases.”
253
The Committee suggested that greater sustainability could be
achieved by the introduction of “a minimum operating period, during
which the cost of any repairs should be borne by the producer.”
254
This
type of regulation would severely reduce the attractiveness of EWSCs.
The initial work by the EU Commission and the EESC was fol-
lowed by additional investigations by other European institutions and
committees aimed at evaluating ways to ensure product durability and to
improve the disclosure of information with respect to product lifetimes.
The Influence of Lifespan Labelling on Consumers study (2016 EESC
Study) concluded that the introduction of lifespan labeling would likely
have a positive effect in terms of the purchase of sustainable products.
255
First, a significant number of consumers would have an interest in ob-
taining information on product lifespans. Second, comprehensible infor-
mation would increase the sale of sustainable products.
256
Also in 2016,
European Parliament’s Committee on Internal Market and Consumer
Protection (IMCO) intermediary report (2016 IMCO Report)
257
con-
cluded that longer product lifetimes (reduction of planned obsolescence)
would produce overall benefits for society, the environment, consumers,
as well as some industrial sectors that would outweigh possible costs.
258
Although extending product lifetimes would reduce the sale of new prod-
ucts, it would create new opportunities in the repair and maintenance
sector as well as product service systems.
259
The 2016 IMCO Report lists
nineteen possible regulatory strategies that range, most notably, from du-
rability labeling to additional consumer support to possible extensions of
251
Id.
252
Id. at 5–6.
253
Id. at 1.
254
Id. at 3.
255
ILLC Study: The Influence of Lifespan Labelling on Consumers, E
UR
. E
CON
. & S
OC
.
C
OMM
. 2, 84 (Mar. 2016), https://www.eesc.europa.eu/resources/docs/16_123_duree-dutilisa
tion-des-produits_complet_en.pdf.
256
Id. at 2. “The results of the test show that lifespan labelling has an influence on
purchasing decisions in favour of products with longer lifespans. On average, sales of products
with a label showing a longer lifespan than competing products increased by 13.8%.” Id.
257
See Carlos Montalvo, Devid Peck & Elmer Rietveld, Directorate-General for Internal
Policies, Comm. on the Internal Mkt. & Consumer Protection, A Longer Lifetime for Products:
Benefits for Consumers and Companies (June 2016), http://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/
etudes/STUD/2016/579000/IPOL_STU(2016)579000_EN.pdf.
258
See id. at 81, 82–83.
259
Id. at 83.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 49 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
531
guarantee periods, as well as mechanisms to monitor planned obsoles-
cence cases.
260
In June 2017, the IMCO released its final report touting the benefits
from prolonging the lifetime of products for benefits for consumers and
companies (2017 IMCO Report).
261
The 2017 IMCO Report was mostly
a restatement of the findings of the 2016 EESC study, the 2016 IMCO
Report, and some earlier studies.
262
The 2017 IMCO Report emphasizes
the expected advantages of longer product lifetimes and explicitly links
the debate to planned obsolescence and the role of guarantees. The Com-
mittee suggested a mix of measures ranging from a closer examination of
alleged obsolescence cases and deterrent strategies (such as whistle
blower protection and undefined “dissuasive measures for producers”) to
encouraging Member States to intensify domestic initiatives.
263
Focusing
predominantly on legal guarantees, the 2017 IMCO Report arrives at a
twofold strategy. First, buyers should receive enhanced, conspicuously
displayed information on their statutory rights.
264
Second, the 2017
IMCO Report suggests that in cases where “the reasonably expected pe-
riod of use [of products] is longer” than the statutorily enshrined guaran-
tee period, refined mechanisms could be introduced.
265
Unfortunately, it
does not define what refined measures would entail, but a tailor-made
approach to setting guarantee periods based upon the expected duration
of given products might arguably be one such measure.
2. Situation in Selected Member States
Parallel to the debates in the EU Parliament and Commission, sev-
eral Member States began to intensify discussions of possible mecha-
nisms to counteract the manipulation of product duration. The first
concrete result was presented in France in 2015, when the legislature
crafted an explicit prohibition of planned obsolescence. The key provi-
sion is found in Article L213-4-1 (I) and (II) of the French Consumer
Code: “Planned obsolescence is defined as any measure with the intent to
conceptually reduce the operating life of a good for economic considera-
tions” and “[i]t is punishable with two years of imprisonment and a fine
260
See id. at 86–88.
261
See Comm. on the Internal Mkt. & Consumer Protection, Report on a Longer Lifetime
for Products: Benefits for Consumers and Companies (June 9, 2017), http://
www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc.do?pubRef=//EP//TEXT+REPORT+A8-2017-0214+0+
DOC+XML+V0//EN [hereinafter 2017 IMCO Report].
262
Id.; see, e.g., TNS Political & Soc., Directorate-General for the Env’t, Attitudes of
Europeans Towards Waste Management and Resource Efficiency (June 2014), ec.europa.eu/
commfrontoffice/publicopinion/flash/fl_388_en.pdf.
263
See 2017 IMCO Report, supra note 261, at 11–12.
264
Id. at 12.
265
Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 50 14-JUN-19 7:19
532
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
of EUR 300,000.”
266
Thus, French lawmakers felt that the shortening of
product lifespans merely for economic reasons (e.g., manufacturer-seller
profits) was serious enough to impose a criminal penalty. A more recent
French strategy includes the possible introduction of a tailor-made life-
time labelling scheme.
267
In 2015, the Italian Parliament considered draft bills on regulating
planned obsolescence. At the time of writing this Article, both initiatives
were still being discussed in the Chamber of Duties.
268
One of the pro-
posed key provisions aims to guarantee the sustainable use of products
by obliging manufacturers to offer spare parts for a minimum period of
five years.
269
Manufacturers and sellers would be required to inform
consumers of their right to repair parts during the statutory period.
270
In 2012, the Belgian Senate passed a resolution on limiting planned
obsolescence requesting the government to develop strategies to combat
planned obsolescence.
271
This project has led to a number of draft bills,
which are currently pending. The proposed approaches range from new
contract law rules to sanctions under criminal law.
272
Other ideas being
discussed, likely influenced by the above studies at the EU level, include
recognizing planned obsolescence as an unfair commercial practice,
lifespan labeling for energy-related goods, and the expansion of legal
guarantees. In the area of guarantee law, potential reforms include the
extension of warranty-legal guarantee periods and adopting a more flexi-
266
Loi 2015-992 du 17 aoˆut 2015 relative a la transition energ´etique pour la croissance` ´
verte [Law 2015-992 of August 17, 2015 on the Energy Transition for Green Growth], J
OUR-
NAL
O
FFICIEL DE LA
R
EPUBLIQUE
F
RANCAISE
] [J.O.] [O
FFICIAL
G
AZETTE OF
F
RANCE
] , Aug.
´
¸
18, 2015, art. L.213-4-1, p. 14263, https://www.legifrance.gouv.fr/affichCodeArticle.do?cid
Texte=LEGITEXT000006069565&idArticle=LEGIARTI000031053376 (translated by an au-
thor of this Article, Stefan Wrbka) [hereinafter French Consumer Code].
267
See Marion Candau, France Pushes for Product ‘Lifetime’ Labeling, E
URACTIV
(Nov.
21, 2018, 12:07 AM), https://www.euractiv.com/section/circular-economy/news/france-
pushes-for-product-lifetime-labelling.
268
See Proposta di Legge 4 november 2015, n.3404, Disposizioni per il Contrasto
del’Obsolescenza Programmata dei Beni di Consume [Draft Provisions on Fighting Planned
Obsolescence of Consumer Goods] (It.), https://parlamento17.openpolis.it/atto/documento/id/
163692 (Known as Camera dei deputati).
269
Id. art. 4(1), at 10.
270
Id. art. 4(4).
271
For its basis, see Senat de Belgique, Session de 2010-2011, Proposition de r´esolution
en vue de lutter contre l’obsolescence programm´ee des produits li´es `a l’´energie [Proposal for
a Resolution to Combat the Planned Obsolescence of Energy-related Products], (Oct. 7,
2011), www.senate.be/www/?MIval=/publications/viewPub.html&COLL=S&LEG=5&NR=
1251&VOLGNR=1&LANG=fr (Belg.) [hereinafter Belgian resolution] (enat de Belgique).
272
See Ana¨ıs Michel, Product Lifetimes through the Various Legal Approaches within the
EU Context: Recent Initiatives Against Planned Obsolescence, PLATE 266, 269 (Conny Bak-
ker & Ruth Mugge eds., 2017) (pointing out that the plans comprise contractual nullity and
reimbursement measures (under the Belgian Civil Code) as well as comparatively strong crim-
inal punishments—with up to five years of imprisonment).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 51 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
533
ble system that takes account of the respective product or product
category.
273
In Germany, there have been a number of political initiatives dis-
cussing strategies for regulating planned obsolescence. Most notably the
German Federal Environment Agency and the German Green Party com-
missioned reports suggesting a proactive regulatory approach towards
ensuring the production of sustainable goods.
274
In 2013, two draft bills
emanating from these studies were introduced.
275
Although neither bill
was passed into law, the initiatives increased the level of visibility of the
problem of planned obsolescence. A more recent 2017 position paper
issued by the German Federal Environment Agency
276
suggests, unlike
the Belgian approach of revising the existing guarantee framework that
would affect all sellers,
277
the implementation of additional guarantees
that would only apply to manufacturers.
278
Under this approach, manu-
facturers would be obligated to guarantee a minimum period of
usability.
279
Austrian legal academics have recently intensified debates on
planned obsolescence in response to greater awareness by public stake-
holders.
280
One of the most active institutions has been the Vienna
Chamber of Labour, which has hosted a number of events on planned
obsolescence and its regulation.
281
It commissioned an expert opinion to
273
Id.
274
See Umweltbundesamt, Einfluss der Nutzungsdauer von Produkten auf ihre
Umweltwirkung: Schaffung einer Informationsgrundlage und Entwicklung von Strategien
gegen ‘Obsoleszenz’ [Strategies Against Obsolescence: Ensuring a Minimum Product Life and
Improving Product Life and Consumer Information] (Nov. 2016), http://www.umwelt
bundesamt.de/sites/default/files/medien/378/publikationen/texte_11_2016_einfluss_der_nut
zungsdauer_von_produkten_obsoleszenz.pdf; Arge Regio, Stadt-und Regionalentwicklung
GmbH, Geplante Obsoleszenz [Planned Obsolescence] (2013), https://www.gruene-
bundestag.de/fileadmin/media/gruenebundestag_de/themen_az/umwelt/PDF/Studie-Obsoles-
zenz-aktuell.pdf (The German Federal Environment Agency is Umweltbundesamt, and the
German Green Party is B¨undnis 90/Die Gr¨unen).
275
D
EUTSCHER
B
UNDESTAG
: D
RUCKSACHEN
[BT] 17/13096 [Printed Matter 17/13096],
17/04/2013, on “Ressourcenschutz durch Vorgabe einer Mindestnutzungsdauer f¨ur technische
Produkte” (Ger.); D
EUTSCHER
B
UNDESTAG
: D
RUCKSACHEN
[BT] 17/13917 [Printed Matter 17/
13917], 12/06/2013, on “Geplanten Verschleib stoppen und die Langlebigkeit von Produkten
sichern” (Ger.).
276
Umweltbundesamt, Strategien gegen Obsoleszenz: Sicherung einer Produktmindestle
bensdauer sowie Verbesserung der Produktnutzungsdauer und der Verbraucherinformation
[Strategies Against Obsolescence] (Nov. 2017).
277
Belgian resolution, supra note 271 and accompanying text.
278
Umweltbundesamt, supra note 274, at 13.
279
Id.
¨
280
See, e.g., H
ELMUT
K
OZIOL
, O
BSOLESZENZEN IM OSTERREICHISCHEN
R
ECHT
:
G
ELTENDES
R
ECHT
, S
CHUTZL
¨
UND
R
EFORMBEDARF
(Wein, Jan Sramek Verlag ed.,
UCKEN
2016).
281
See, e.g., R
ENATE
H
UBNER
, G
EKAUFT UND SCHON KAPUTT
. L
EBEN IN EINER
¨
W
EGWERFGESELLSCHAFT
? (2013).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 52 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
534
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
evaluate the use of legal guarantees in obsolescence cases.
282
In 2014,
the Austrian Standards Institute took a pioneering role in the lifespan
labelling movement by issuing the non-binding “Label of Excellence”
for durable, repair-friendly designed electrical and electronic appli-
ances.
283
It recommends the use of specific labels to indicate compliance
with a minimum period of usability—five years in the case of brown
goods (home entertainment equipment) and ten years with respect to
white goods (household appliances).
284
This trend relating to the issue of
planned obsolescence or minimum levels of durability is likely to con-
tinue in Austria.
Finally, it should be pointed out that a number of Member States
have extended or, alternatively, have diversified or created tailored legal
guarantee periods to cover as many obsolescence cases as possible. Par-
ticularly noteworthy in this respect are the flexible regimes found in the
Netherlands and Finland. In both jurisdictions the regulatory schemes
now take account of different product types and link the guarantee dura-
tion to the expected average lifetimes of the products.
285
IV. R
ECOMMENDATIONS FOR
R
EGULATORY
R
EFORM
There are various conceivable approaches to dealing with the ma-
nipulation of product life by manufacturers and the related issue of the
sales of EWSCs tailored to expire within those lifespans. The simplest
approach would simply be to refine the law to require longer warranties.
This would require the recognition of planned obsolescence as a hidden
or latent defect. As such, the fixed manufacturer warranty period would
be tolled until the discovery of the product’s lack of durability. In sum,
the law would recognize a connection between warranty and planned
obsolescence.
A more preferable approach would be to enact a new regulatory
scheme based upon the disclosure of information and more free market
friendly forms of self-regulation. Such an approach would incentivize
282
S
TEFAN
W
RBKA
, G
EPLANTE
O
BSOLESZENZ AUS
S
ICHT DES
G
EW
¨
AHRLEISTUNGSRECHTS
(2015).
283
Austrian Standards Institute, ONR 192102:2014, G¨ ¨utezeichen fur langlebige,
reparaturfreundlich konstruierte elektrische und elektronische Ger¨ate [Label of Excellence for
Durable, Repair-Friendly Designed Electrical and Electronic Appliances] (2014).
284
Id. criteria 10, 40.
285
In Finland, this task falls on an ombudsman, who has the competence to define the
expectable product lifetimes. See Statutory Liability for Lack of Conformity and Guarantee in
the Sale of Consumer Goods, F
INNISH
C
OMPETITION
& C
ONSUMER
A
UTH
. (Aug. 8, 2018),
https://www.kkv.fi/en/decisions-and-publications/publications/consumer-ombudsmans-guide
lines/by-subject/statutory-liability-for-lack-of-conformity-and-guarantee-in-the-sale-of-consu
mer-goods/; see also 2017 IMCO Report, supra note 261 (referencing specific measures intro-
duced in additional Member States); supra discussion in note 262–64 & infra discussion in
note 305.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 53 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
R
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
535
manufacturers to brand the durability of their products, thus allowing
manufacturers to differentiate their products, while at the same time im-
proving consumer protection.
There are numerous existing templates relating to safety, quality,
health, and environmental standards and regulations, such as energy effi-
ciency standards. Also in place are customary lifetime ratings and disclo-
sures for items such as automobile tires and batteries, windshield wiper
blades, other types of batteries (flashlight, electronic devices), light
bulbs, and so forth.
286
Thus, there are three currently plausible approaches to the regula-
tion of product durability and EWSCs. First, reforming current warranty
law by mandating longer durations to cover the period for planned obso-
lescence. Second, requiring additional information disclosures similar to
energy efficiency disclosures that estimate the lifetime efficiency of a
product. Third, combining extended warranty periods with disclosure of
expected lifespan information. Existing examples of the third approach
are seen in twenty-year-rated tires or twenty-year-rated roof shingles,
which allow a pro rata price credit on replacement tires or shingles based
upon the actual lifetime of the product. Replacement ratings are subject
to manipulation by manufacturers or rating agencies, but such manipula-
tion would be a case of fraud that could be regulated privately through
litigation or through statutory regulations. Such required disclosures are
likely to incentivize manufacturers to produce more durable products to
protect the marketability of their brand. Presently, most consumers use
price as a surrogate for quality, denying them the choice of buying a
lesser-priced product with an as long or longer life span.
287
A. Initial Considerations
This Section highlights the most striking conclusions derived from
the current research. Based on these conclusions a number of regulatory
approaches will be examined and recommendations will be offered. For
the purpose of clarification, before assessing regulatory options it first
needs to be determined, from a sustainability perspective, the reasons
why consumers consider the purchase of EWSCs. The 2015 Market
286
There are also numerous private rating services for durable products. For example,
Consumer Reports rate refrigerators on a number of criteria including “predicted reliability.”
See Refrigerators, C
ONSUMER
R
EPORTS
, https://www.consumerreports.org/products/bottom-
freezer-refrigerator/ratings-overview. Some national “experiments” have been initiated on a
few European countries such the initiative by the Austrian Standards Institute, supra note 283
(proposing voluntary lifetime labelling). Such labelling allows manufacturers to brand their
products as satisfactorily durable. See also supra notes 266–67 (discussing France’s legal re-
gime) and notes 271–73 (discussing Belgium’s legal regime).
287
Although some consumers may choose less durability for high-tech products with
shorter lifespans because they are susceptible to defects that have higher repair costs.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 54 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
536
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
Study on guarantees makes a commonsensical conclusion that consumers
who pay for EWSCs do so because they want additional protection in
fear of obsolescence and the high costs of repair that makes an extended
guarantee period appealable.
288
This was verified in the Market Study’s
listing of the most common consumer responses as wanting a “longer
guarantee coverage period,” “peace of mind,” and “cost of repairing the
product would be too high.”
289
In short, most consumers, with the excep-
tion of those who purposely purchase disposable items prefer purchasing
durable goods; and these consumers are disappointed by or fear relatively
short technical product lifetimes, as well as the high costs of repairs,
whether real or imagined. It is this irrational fear that makes consumers
susceptible to the high-pressure sales tactics discussed at the beginning
of this Article, and it is also the reason that sellers of EWSC are able to
charge exorbitant prices.
The current state of EWSCs and the profitability of this growing
industry works against the durability interests of consumers. The rise in
popularity of EWSCs incentivized manufacturers and sellers of EWSCs
to capitalize on obsolescence. From an alternative perspective, the
EWSC market is a market of the manufacturers’ own creation. Planned
obsolescence may have been motivated by economic motives to increase
future sales and the product repair market. But, it soon became apparent
that the period from the expiration of the express warranty and the end of
the time of planned obsolescence provided a new avenue for profit.
Based on the vulnerability of purchasers of automobiles and durable
products, enhanced marketing techniques were developed in the creation
of the EWSC marketplace.
The above scenario has resulted in a vicious cycle. Producers have
an interest in shortening product lifetimes to force end-users to buy new
products more frequently. At the same time, the EWSC and “genuine”
insurance markets flourish because consumers are willing, with the en-
couragement of manufacturer-sellers, to purchase additional coverage.
While this is not always necessarily an abuse in the strict sense, it
presents a number of moral hazard problems—questionable shortening
of product lifecycles and marketing of dubious and non-transparent
EWSCs—that should be removed through additional regulations of the
EWSCs market.
Before going into detail, regulation for the sake of regulation may
have unintended consequences, so what is needed is a refinement of cur-
rent warranty law or new, targeted regulation of planned obsolescence
and EWSCs. The focus should be put on efficiency and effectiveness.
The main characteristic of an appropriate EWSC regulatory framework
288
See Market Study, supra note 1, at 92–93.
289
Id.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 55 14-JUN-19 7:19
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
537
must include ideas on product sustainability within the parameters of
fairness, informed-decision making, product durability, proportionality
(lowest possible or necessary degree of state interference), and consumer
satisfaction. The following suggestions and considerations all address
one or more of these concepts.
B. Generalized Versus Specialized Rules
There has been a long running theoretical debate over the benefits
of a general rules regime versus specialized bodies of rules.
290
General-
ization is the essence of the common law of contracts and civil codes.
Contract law’s abstractness is needed because its rules and principles
must be applied to various, disparate types of contracts. The benefits of
generalized rules are that they provide a single place in which contractual
obligations are predicated. The twentieth century has witnessed the de-
velopment of specialized bodies of rules for particular transaction
types.
291
The most obvious preemption of the common law of contracts
in the U.S. was the adoption of the UCC with its specialized rules for
sale of goods, leasing of goods, letters of credit, secured transactions, and
negotiable instruments. However, American contract law has retained its
generality regarding commercial and consumer contracts. The same set
of contract rules apply to both. In contrast, EU Directives outlined in this
Article have diminished the generality of contract law, so much so that it
can be said that there is a separate consumer contract law in the EU.
Before specialized bodies of rules are adopted, the costs of develop-
ing and applying such rules need to be balanced against the benefits of
retaining a general law of contracts. This balance can be determined by
asking: (1) has the general law of contracts become obsolete or an ill fit
for a particular type of contract? (2) Does the general law of contracts
fail to provide adequate or comprehensive coverage of an evolving con-
tract-type? (3) Does the particular contract or transaction-type
292
require
a specialized body of rules to deal with issues not adequately dealt with
by the general law of contracts? These questions may be applied to
290
See e.g., Nathan B. Oman, Bargaining in the Shadow of God’s Law: Islamic Mahr
Contracts and the Perils of Legal Specialization, 45 W
AKE
F
OREST
L. R
EV
. 579, 582 (2010)
(asserting that the common law of contracts was a better fit for Islamic marriage contracts than
the specialized rules of divorce law or prenuptial agreements); Nathan B. Oman, A Pragmatic
Defense of Contract Law, 98 G
EO
. L.J. 77 (1990) (reviewing the critiques of general contract
law).
291
See Christopher T. Wonnell, The Abstract Character of Contract Law, 22 C
ONN
. L.
R
EV
. 437, 440–42 (1990) (documenting the diminishment of abstraction in contract law).
292
Karl Llewellyn, a founder of the American Legal Realist Movement and Reporter of
the UCC, coined terms such as transaction-types and situation sense, which were core concepts
in his view of contract law as specialized areas of contract types, in which the application of
contract law is context dependent. See K
ARL
L
LEWELLYN
, T
HE
C
OMMON
L
AW
T
RADITION
:
D
ECIDING
A
PPEALS
260, 368 (1960).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 56 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
538
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
EWSCs as a new type of contract in need of specialized rules to prevent
overreaching by the manufacturer-seller.
The common law’s continual insistence that consumer contracts are
the product of true consent has prevented the creation of a body of spe-
cialized rules relating to consumer contract law. The likelihood of the
adoption of specialized consumer contract law even in the long-term is
slim. One of the questions presented in this Article is whether EWSCs
deserve a special body of rules to prevent consumer abuse. The issues
raised throughout this Article strongly indicate that, at the very least, a
set of explicit rules is necessary given the size of the EWSC industry.
293
The new approaches, as discussed in this Article, taken by the EU and
some EU Member States support the need for express, specialized rules
relating to the sale of EWSCs. Developments in Europe emphasize the
“practical relevance”
294
of EWSCs by introducing specific regulatory
concepts. However, there has been no recognition as to the best method
of regulating the EWSC industry. Most EU countries have no specialized
regulations, while some countries, such as Austria and Germany, have
taken first steps in regulating EWSCs as a separate product area. The
problem of planned obsolescence lags behind the study of EWSCs re-
quiring more investigation and deliberations at the EU and Member State
levels. With the exception of the remarkably specific regulation of
planned obsolescence in France,
295
no other countries at this time have
enacted tailored law on this subject.
C. Comprehensive and Specialized Laws are Needed
The current state of affairs relating to EWSCs presents numerous
issues that to a large extent have already been addressed in Europe, but
have yet to be met by stronger regulations in the U.S. Some of the issues
that should be regulated include: (1) how long can the administrator (re-
pairer) keep an automobile or other product in order to make necessary
repairs? (2) What are the consumer’s legal rights when the product has to
be continuously repaired? (3) Should the seller of an EWSC be required
to subtract the product warranty period from the advertised EWSC pe-
riod?
296
(4) Should the seller of a service contract be required to disclose
if the product is or is not likely to need repairs or the expected costs of
293
There are other instances where the American law of contracts has developed special-
ized rules for troublesome clauses, such as covenants not-to-compete and liquidated-penalty
clauses. See, e.g., U.C.C. § 2-718.
294
Practical relevance signifies that an issue is of substantial importance to the common
market to warrant investigation and possible enactment of law.
295
See supra note 266–67 and accompanying text.
296
For example, instead of representing the period of the EWSC as 8 years, the seller
must represent it as a 5-year duration because of duplicate coverage of the 3 years provided
under the product warranty.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 57 14-JUN-19 7:19
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
539
repairs?
297
(5) Should the seller be required to alert the consumer to any
exemptions from liability in the service contract, such as a clause al-
lowing the company to deny coverage if the consumer fails to follow
instructions for routine maintenance? (6) Should the seller be required to
alert the consumer of expenses not covered by the service contract?
298
(7) Should specific regulations be imposed on after-point-of-sale market-
ers of EWSCs (cold call or mail solicitations) that use high-pressure sales
tactics, often requesting a deposit or financial information before actually
providing the terms of the contract? Affirmative answers to these ques-
tions seem to be reasonable and rational. The following Sections explore
strategies for responding to the above questions.
D. Improving Informed Decision-Making
Informed decision-making refers to strategies aimed to provide con-
sumers with the information needed to make rational decisions. But since
human beings possess “bounded rationality,”
299
too much information is
likely to be ignored or not fully processed by the purchaser. How infor-
mation is delivered is just as important as the actual disclosure or content
of the information. Few consumers read overly long and detailed form
contracts or long lists of online terms and conditions.
300
There are two
elements to information dissemination: one from the seller’s and the
297
Such information surely exists and can be disclosed. An example by analogy is the
current controversy in American law school admissions, where likeliness of passing the bar
exam is available. Evidence shows a strong connection between law school admission test
scores (LSAT) and the likelihood of passing the bar exam. Some schools have lowered admis-
sion standards so low that they are admitting students in the bottom 8% of LSAT test scores,
thus resulting in low bar exam passing rates. This and other relevant information are not dis-
closed to law school applicants, making this a potential case of misrepresentation or fraud.
This allows the law schools to continue their revenues flows, while leaving their students with
high student loan debt and worthless degrees. See Myanna Dellinger, Desperate Times for Law
Schools, C
ONTRACTS
P
ROF
B
LOG
(Nov. 21, 2017), https://lawprofessors.typepad.com/contract-
sprof_blog/2017/11/desperate-times-for-law-schools.html.
298
These questions were derived from information provided by the U.S. FTC. See Col-
leen Tressler (Consumer Education Specialist), Warranties and Service Contracts 101, C
ON-
SUMER
I
NFO
., F
ED
. T
RADE
C
OMM
N
(Jan. 15, 2015), https://www.consumer.ftc.gov/blog/2015/
01/warranties-and-service-contracts-101; Extended Warranties and Service Contracts, C
ON-
SUMER
I
NFO
., F
ED
. T
RADE
C
OMM
N
, https://www.consumer.ftc.gov/articles/0240-extended-
warranties-and-service-contracts (last visited May. 2, 2019).
299
Bounded rationality recognizes that humans use heuristics or short cuts in making
quasi-rational decisions. Even if full information is provided or is available, humans generally
will not take the time or possess the cognitive capacity to process the information. See Amos
Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, 185 S
CI
.
1124, 1124 (1974) (discussing the use of heuristics and related biases to assess and predict
uncertainties); Melvin Aron Eisenberg, The Limits of Cognition and the Limits of Contract, 47
S
TAN
. L. R
EV
. 211, 212 (1995) (using behavioral biases to justify regulations in contract law);
Cass R. Sunstein, Behavioral Analysis of Law, 64 U. C
HI
. L. R
EV
. 1175, 1179–93 (1997)
(reviewing a list of heuristics and biases).
300
See S
TEFAN
W
RBKA
, E
UROPEAN
C
ONSUMER
A
CCESS TO
J
USTICE
R
EVISITED
292–94
(2015) (discussing American and European studies).
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 58 14-JUN-19 7:19
540
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
other from the buyer’s perspective. First, sellers through the manipula-
tion of information, emphasizing only positive features or using high-
pressure sales tactics, are able to frame the desirability of the EWSC.
Second, the reception of the information by the purchaser—characteris-
tics like prior experiences,
301
level of sophistication, and independent re-
search—can counter the manipulative presentations of information.
These two elements are intimately interconnected. The binary nature of
informational manipulation and bounded rationality is a core reason for
regulatory intervention. For example, if key information is required to be
presented in a conspicuous and intelligible manner, then the buyer will
be better able to process the benefits and costs of the EWSC.
In the present context, effective information disclosure must include
posting or marking the expected period of usability of products. In this
sense, effective information would allow buyers interested in purchasing
durable products to make informed decisions. Arguably the most effec-
tive strategy is using “durability labels” that follow the example of EU
“eco labels.” In 1992, the EU introduced a color-coded energy consump-
tion label with a classification of covered goods, largely household
goods, and then was extended to other types of products.
302
Under the
eco label scheme, products are classified, with a letter grade with the
most eco-friendly products given an “A” rating.
303
The energy consump-
tion labels contain intelligible information and have become an integral
part of the consumer and commercial marketplaces.
To provide buyers with a comparable degree of comprehensibility,
tailor-made durability labels could be introduced to signify the expected
lifespans of products. This is, for example, highlighted by more recent
policy discussions in the EU, where a number of national policy-makers
301
Behavioral law and economics have shown that biases, such as prior experience, often
intervene to prevent the decision-maker from making a less than rational decision. See Amos
Tversky & Daniel Kahneman, Availability: A Heuristic for Judging Frequency and
Probability, 5 C
OGNITIVE
P
SYCHOL
. 207 (1973) (describing a heuristic that predicts that people
evaluate risk more seriously when a past incident is readily called to mind).
302
The color code runs from green to red. One of the most recent examples is the provi-
sional agreement between the EU Parliament, Council, and Commission to identify the energy
performance of buildings. See, e.g. Welcomes Agreement on Energy Performance of Buildings,
E
UROPEAN
C
OMMISSION
(Dec. 19, 2017), http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-17-
5129_en.htm (proposing new legislative methods for improving the energy performance of
buildings).
303
See Council Directive 92/75/EEC of 22 September 1992 on the Indication by Label-
ling and Standard Product Information of the Consumption of Energy and Other Resources by
Household Appliances, 1992 O.J. (L 297) 16, 17, repealed by Directive 2010/30/EU of the
European Parliament and of the Council of 19 May 2010 on the Indication by Labelling and
Standard Product Information of the Consumption of Energy and Other Resources by Energy-
Related Products, 2010 O.J. (L 153) 1, 1, further repealed by Regulation (EU) 2017/1369 of
the European Parliament and of the Council of 4 July 2017 Setting a Framework for Energy
Labelling and Repealing Directive 2010/30/EU, 2017 O.J. (L 198) 1.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 59 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
541
have given this topic serious consideration.
304
A two-level labeling sys-
tem would signify the expected durability of comparable products, prod-
ucts of the same category and identify the evaluated lifespan of a specific
product, Durability Level 1 and Durability Level 2.
One of the parameters to determine the general expected durability
would be the overall level of technical development with respect to a
product category. Examples of systems utilizing the first level or type of
durability include the Finnish ombudsman system’s defining of expected
usability periods and the labeling initiative of the Austrian Standards In-
stitute, which were previously discussed.
305
The Durability Level 1 refers
to a durability period that function as a mandatory minimum standard for
products that are not explicitly sold as “disposable products.” Durability
Level 2 adds a more flexible system that gives manufacturers of longer-
lasting products the chance to label them as more durable in order to
attract potential buyers with strong preferences for sustainability. This
two-fold durability label scheme would allow a clearer linkage between
sustainable products and guarantees.
A durability rating system would enhance an informed decision-
making process. Added value to such a rating system would include the
provision for comprehensive information on the applicable guarantee
schemes. To vest potential purchasers with the ability to assess the value
of an EWSC, guarantees should be required to provide concise, intelligi-
ble, accurate, and appropriately complete information in a visible way.
The effectiveness of this disclosure regime would be improved through
effective enforcement and stakeholder guidance. The importance of en-
forcement and guidance will be discussed in a subsequent section.
306
In summary, producers should be required to comply with sus-
tainability and guarantee labeling standards. The benefits of such
mandatory disclosures would include increased consumer confidence,
stimulation of competition in the production of more innovative, durable,
and eco-friendly products. The EWSC market would need to be re-
tooled; the new disclosure requirements would incentivize sellers of
EWSCs to design more attractive guarantees.
E. Refined Warranty Regime
A three-level guarantee framework would provide an optimal mix
of legal, integral (no-cost), and paid-for EWSCs while also maximizing
the potential of durability labeling schemes. Following the examples of
304
See supra Part IV.H.
305
See supra note 285 (discussing the Finnish ombudsman scheme); supra notes 280–84
(discussing the Austrian Standards Institute’s initiative).
306
See infra Part IV.F.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 60 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
542
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
the Netherlands and Finland,
307
products would be classified into prod-
uct-specific durability categories that determine the generally expected
minimum period of usability for that respective product category. These
periods would further define the length of the respective legal guaran-
tee—the duration of legal guarantees would principally follow the dura-
bility period of the respective product category.
308
Manufactures who want to produce longer-lasting products would
be able to attract customers interested in long product lifespans or con-
sumers who are eco-minded. The manufacturer would signal its products
durability with a Durability label. To ensure the functionality of the re-
spective product during the longer durability periods and to prevent mis-
leading information, the respective product would have to provide an
extended guarantee or integral EWSC at no additional cost, covering the
time between the expiration of the legal guarantee and the durability pe-
riod stated in the Durability label. Optional EWSCs could then be offered
to customers wanting protection beyond the legal guarantee and integral
EWSCs. Thus, adding a third level of guarantees. Such a scheme would
create a level playing field for stakeholders participating in the sale of
goods and guarantees EWSC markets through enhanced transparency
and comprehensibility.
The three-level scheme proposed above may lead to further diversi-
fication of the market and greater consumer choice. First, some manufac-
turers might want to produce less durable, “disposable” products with
expected durations shorter than the generally expected duration of goods
in the same product category. This goes hand in hand with the interests
of buyers who want to purchase less durable products, in particular if
they come at a significantly lower price. To accommodate this market,
the above-tiered system of guarantees would need to be fine-tuned with a
shorter running time than the generally expected. This exception would
be consistent with the goal of informed decision-making if such products
were visibly and clearly labeled as “less durable than the standard” of
durability of that category of products. This would be consistent with
preventing the manipulation of information tied to planned obsolescence
and the overpricing of EWSCs. The labeling of goods as less durable
aligns planned obsolescence with informed decision-making.
Second, it must be noted that there are a variety of EWSC-like prod-
ucts whose purpose is not to temporarily extend the duration of guarantee
periods, but to provide for extra services, such as enhanced repair ser-
vices or extending liability to other parties. Such variety or diversifica-
tion, whether in products or in paid for guarantees is a good thing as long
307
See supra note 285 (outlining the Finnish ombudsman scheme).
308
Exceptions and shorter legal guarantee durations apply with respect to disposable
products.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 61 14-JUN-19 7:19
R
2019]
P
LANNED
O
BSOLESCENCE AND
C
ONSUMER
P
ROTECTION
543
as the strict standards of clarity and comprehensibility proposed above
are applied.
F. Enhanced Support and Enforcement
The studies, reports and initiatives referred to in this Article indicate
a lack of transparency on product durability coupled with unintelligible
or misleading information and slick selling tactics in the sale of EWSCs.
The 2014 Sweep on Guarantees in the Electronic Goods Sector high-
lighted the practical issues in the sale of such extended guarantees as
their failure to reference applicable, mandatory legal guarantees and
overlapping coverage. For example, does the EWSC extend the duration
of coverage beyond the legal guarantee or does it merely provide some
additional services?
New regulatory requirements for the use of clear, intelligible lan-
guage in EWSCs offers a certain degree of improvement. But in many
instances, existing regulatory language remains imperfect for EWSCs.
Article 6(2) CSD, for example, seems to be comparatively precise when
it states that EWSCs should “set out in plain intelligible language the
contents of the guarantee and the essential particulars necessary for mak-
ing claims under the guarantee, notably the duration and territorial scope
of the guarantee as well as the name and address of the guarantor.” In
practice, however, the lack of concrete guidelines has made application
of these requirements problematic. Hence, a more precise substantive
regulatory regime would denote clear, specific requirements and criteria.
The 2014 Guarantee Sweep and comparable projects show the
EWSC market is characterized by a considerably high degree of non-
compliance with existing rules. Thus, a refined regulatory scheme needs
to be coupled with enhanced enforcement. In modification of the motto
ubi non accusator ibi non iudex” (“where there is no claimant, there is
no judge”), one of the most proportionate and adequate ways would be to
establish information and monitoring authorities. Such authorities should
be imbued with competencies to launch enforcement actions. The market
surveillance activities (sweeps) performed under the CPC Regulation
have been a highly effective mechanism to identify shortcomings in ex-
isting regulations and cases of non-compliance. As repeatedly shown, the
actions launched by competent government agencies or private institu-
tions
309
have significantly improved the level of pertinent compliance.
310
309
To assist market surveillance institutions, local and nationwide business and consumer
information centers could support substantive regulation and help to decrease levels of non-
transparency and incomprehensibility, and limit the necessity to involve courts and other dis-
pute resolution bodies.
310
For more information on the CPC Regulation sweeps conducted prior to 2015, see,
e.g., S
TEFAN
W
RBKA
, E
UROPEAN
C
ONSUMER
A
CCESS TO
J
USTICE
R
EVISITED
66–67 with further
references. For information on more recent sweeps see, e.g. Sweeps, supra note 207.
\\jciprod01\productn\C\CJP\28-3\CJP304.txt unknown Seq: 62 14-JUN-19 7:19
544
C
ORNELL
J
OURNAL OF
L
AW AND
P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
[Vol. 28:483
In some cases, non-complying businesses do not possess sufficient
knowledge of the law or elect to strategically non-comply.
311
However,
in cases of intentional non-compliance or partial compliance, harsher ac-
tions are needed, such as standing to sue for overpricing and injunctions,
and decertification for repeat offenders.
C
ONCLUSION
There are many regulatory gaps in the law; rightly so, otherwise,
overregulation would smother the free market system. A balance needs
to be struck between freedom of contract and the regulatory need to en-
sure a fair marketplace. This balance has been recalibrated from time to
time. Human and societal preferences are the bases of capitalism; as
such, they have increasingly defined that balance as creating an eco-
friendly, sustainable use of resources, fair and competitive markets that
encourage technological advancements and innovation in the interests of
consumers in a transparent, rights-observing marketplace. Achieving
such a balance requires greater disclosure of the durability of products so
that consumers and other purchasers are provided the means to make
informed decisions. Currently, the Extended Warranty-Service Contract
(EWSC) market can be characterized as unfair, non-transparent, and
overreaching (price gouging). Studies support the view that a truly sus-
tainable marketplace would benefit from regulation of this growing
market.
This Article discusses both the EWSC markets and the phenomenon
of planned obsolescence (products engineered to fail prematurely) in the
United States and Europe. Both pose challenges from the viewpoint of
creating a fair and level playing field. Most notably, concerns include the
absence of clear regulatory rules and, in cases where such rules exist,
there have been numerous enforcement issues. Recommendations are
provided for the creation of more comprehensive and effective rules to
ensure procedural fairness in the purchase of EWSCs: labeling schemes,
refined techniques of enforcement, monitoring, and support institutions.
In effectuating such rules, the phenomenon of planned obsolescence can
be brought out of the shadows and made transparent in the marketplace.
In the end, the regulation of EWSCs and the issue of planned obsoles-
cence are inherently interconnected.
311
See Daniel T. Ostas, Cooperate, Comply, or Evade? A Corporate Executive’s Social
Responsibilities with Regard to Law, 41 A
M
. B
US
. L.J. 559 (2004) (arguing that businesses do
not have an absolute duty to obey the law). The reciprocal reversion of strategic compliance is
strategic enforcement. See Margaret H. Lemos & Alex Stein, Strategic Enforcement, 95 M
INN
.
L. R
EV
. 9 (2010).