(1881)
ARTICLE
CONTRACT PRODUC TION IN M&A MARKETS
STE PHEN J. CHOI,
MITU G ULATI,
††
MATTHEW JENNEJOHN
†††
&
ROBERT E. SCOTT
††††
Contract scholarship has devoted considerable attention to how contract terms are
designed to incentivize parties to fulll their obligations. Less attention has been paid
to the production of contracts and the tradeos between using boilerplate terms and
designing bespoke provisions. In thick markets everyone uses the standard form despite
the known drawbacks of boilerplate. But in thinne r markets, such as the private deal
M&A world, parties trade o costs and benets of using standard provisions and
customizing clauses. This Article reports on a case study of contract production in the
M&A markets. We nd evidence of an informal information network that transforms
bespoke changes in contract terms into industry-wide standard provisions. This
organic coordination structure leads to both market-wide coordination as well as a
diversity in this response as individual actors implement bespoke variations of the
new standard.
Bernard Petrie Professor of Law and Business, New York University School of Law.
††
Perre Bowen Professor of Law and John V. Ray Research Professor of Law, University of
Virginia School of Law.
†††
Professor of Law, BYU Law School.
††††
Alfred McCormack Professor Emeritus of Law, Columbia Law School. The authors thank
Ken Ayotte, Elisabeth de Fontenay, Jerey Dutson, Peter Lyons, Peter Molk, Michael Ohlrogge,
Samir Parikh, George Triantis, Glenn West, and participants at the University of Pennsylvania Law
Review’s symposium on Debt Market Complexity for comments, the editors of the Law Review for
their improvements, and to Sarah Lucas, Miranda Bailey, Tyler Baird, Paige Dallimore, C.J.
Jasperson, Alexandra Jorgensen, Jennifer Kimball, Tara Lee, Emily Livingston, Mickala Mahaey,
Samuel McMurray, Kelly Miles, Taylor Petersen, Aubrey Reed, Ethan Schow, Maria Whitaker,
Teresa White, and Kyle Wilson for research assistance. Thanks to Annalee Hickman Pierson and
Iantha Haight for library support. Finally, thanks to our thirty respondents.
1882 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
I
NTRODUCTION............................................................................ 1882
I. T
HE PRODUCTION OF CONTRACTS IN BOTH THIN AND T HI CK
MARKETS ............................................................................... 1888
A. Bespoke Contracting in Thin Markets...........................................1889
B. Production Eciencies in Thick Markets ...................................... 1891
C. The Collective Action Problem and the Role of the M&A Network...1893
II. CONTRACTING OVE R FRAUD: INCORPORATING NEW LAW
INTO
STANDARD TERMS ......................................................... 1895
A. From No-Reliance Clauses to the Fraud Carve-Out .......................1895
B. ABRY Partners: From the Fraud Carve-Out to Limited Fraud
Clauses .................................................................................... 1897
III. U
NPACKING THE NETWORK ....................................................1899
A. Leading Law Firms as a Spider................................................... 1901
B. The Inuence of the Voluntary Spider...........................................1902
C. The Inuence of Multilevel, Collective Engagement .......................1903
D. Summary .................................................................................1905
IV. EMPIRICAL DATA AN D ANALYSIS ............................................. 1905
A. The Fraud Carve-Out ...............................................................1908
B. Dening Fraud : The Incidence of Limited Fraud Clauses................ 1910
C. Digging Deeper: Who Moved First and How Fast? ........................ 1912
D. Deeper Still: Variation in Limited Fraud Provisions ....................... 1916
C
ONCLUSION................................................................................ 1924
I
NTRODUCTION
Two separate economic objectives motivate the parties who form
commercial contracts.
1
A primary objective is to design contracts that induce
the parties to maximize the joint gains from transactions. This is the goal of
ecient contract design.
2
But contracting parties also pursue a second
objective: they must conceive and formulate the many legal terms and
conditions that implement their contract design. This is the goal of ecient
contract production. Until recently, the ecient production objective has been
largely unexplored. We know a great deal about how to design contracts to
motivate parties to invest optimally in their relationships, but we know less
1
Portions of the Introduction & Part I draw from Robert E. Scott, The Paradox of Contracting
in Markets, 83 L
AW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 71 (2020).
2
See Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law, 113 YALE
L.J. 541, 544-45 (2003) (“[C]ontract law should facilitate the eorts of contracting parties to
maximize the joint gains . . . from transactions [by solving the] canonical ‘contracting problem of
ensuring both ecient ex post trade and ecient ex ante investment . . . .”).
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1883
about the process of producing the widely-used contract terms that
implement the ecient design.
3
This is unfortunate because the production
process is the source of a fundamental tradeo: the factors that generate
eciencies in the production of contracts—standardization and economies of
scale—are the same factors that can undermine ecient design by
instantiating contract terms that do not (or no longer) maximize the parties’
joint gains. And the reverse is true: customized eorts to formulate terms
that implement an ecient de sign necessarily generate the ineciencies in
contract production that result from the inevitable loss of scale. As a
consequence, while partie s in thin markets may prefer more bespoke contracts
that minimize errors in design, parties in thick markets, where more and more
parties participate in the same or similar transactions, may prefer
standardization and economies of scale even at the risk of an increase in
design errors.
4
Recognizing this tradeo is the rst step toward answering an unresolved
question: how do contracting parties optimize between the ecient contract
production and ecient contract design? The challenge is to exploit
production eciencies without degrading the contract design that motivates
ecient performance.
5
In understanding how commercial parties respond to
this tradeo we can begin with a more precise identication of the production
costs of contracting. Contract drafters that are faithful agents are motivated
to optimi ze two principal costs: the cost of production eorts and design error
3
For examples of eorts to understand the production problem, see Stephen J. Choi, Mitu
Gulati & Robert E. Scott, The Black Hole Problem in Commercial Boilerplate, 67 D
UKE L.J. 1, 12-14
(2017) (exploring how certain contract provisions are created and evolve over time); see also Robert
Anderson & Jerey Manns, The Inecient Evolution of Merger Agreements, 85 G
EO. WASH. L. REV.
57, 59-61 (2017) (analyzing the evolution and relatedness of public company merger agreement
language); Barak Richman, Contracts Meet Henry Ford, 40 H
OFSTRA L. REV. 77, 85-86 (2011)
(postulating that organizational tendencies toward the routine may explain the reproduction of
boilerplate language in contracts); D. Gordon Smith & Brayden G. Smith, Contracts as Organizations,
51 A
RIZ. L.REV. 1, 2 (2009) (arguing that recent studies of contract language have been too narrowly
focused on economic theories of contracting and should take organizational theory into account);
Kevin E. Davis, Interpreting Boilerplate 1-2 (N.Y.U . Ctr. for L., Econ., & Org., Working Paper No .
10-21, 2010), http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1618925 [https://perma.cc/JCE9-
SBDU]; Weija Rao & Cree Jones, Sticky BITs, 61 H
ARV. INTL L.J. 357, 360 (2020) (analyzing
national uptake of new bilateral treaty provisions in response to unexpected judicial treaty
interpretations); Julian Nyarko, Stickiness and Incomplete Contracts, 88 U.
CHI. L. REV. 1, 6-7 (2021)
(identifying and explaining the absence of bargaining over dispute settlement clauses in commercial
transactions).
4
For our purposes, a market is thick when many parties participate in similar transactions and
will benet from coordinated responses to the contracting environment. Thus, a market thickens
when more and more parties participate in the same or similar transactions.
5
As we discuss in Part I, when markets are thick in the sense that many actors face similar
challenges in their dealings, the aected parties often will institutionalize their innovative contract
forms and terms through collective action. Infra Part I.
1884 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
costs.
6
Eorts and error costs are substitutes: the more time and eort a
drafter spends in producing a contract, ceteris peribus, the lower the risk of
design error. Conversely, the less time and eort invested in production the
higher the risk of unwanted errors.
To frame the problem, we begin by examining the poles of a production
continuum with maximum production eort cost and minimum design error
cost at one pole and minimum production eort cost and maximum design
error cost at the other. At one pole, parties in thin markets where contracting
is bilateral are impelled by their circumstances to use substantial eorts in
production that will tend to minimize design errors for each transaction. For
example, the parties can avoid errors by updating each contract in response
to legal or economic conditions: coordinating with other transactors is not a
concern.
7
By contrast, at the other pole, where markets are thick, traders can
exploit economies of scale by standardizing the production of the contracts
that govern their transaction. Standardization substantially reduces the
transaction costs of producing contract terms by providing a prescribed menu
of incentive-compatible terms. However, this standardization, most clearly
found in large liquid markets such as those for cor porate and sovereign bonds,
leads to the ineciencies common to boilerplate: deviating from the standard
is costly and updating requires coordination among many diverse interests.
Thus, while boilerplate te rms require minimal investment in production cost,
they are sticky, resistant to change, and subject to the anomalies we have
previously described as “black holes”
8
and “landmines”
9
—errors that remain
in the contract even in the face of adverse legal consequences.
10
6
We dene design error costs as the failure of any contract term to embody optimal contract
design; that is the failure to formulate a term that will (together with the other contract terms)
maximize the expected contractual surplus.
7
In eect, it is the contracting parties attempt to maximize “the incentive bang for the
contracting-cost buck. Robert E. Scott & George G. Triantis, Anticipating Litigation in Contract
Design, 115 Y
ALE L.J. 814, 823 (2006).
8
See Stephen J. Choi, Mitu Gulati & Robert E. Scott, The Black Hole Problem in Commercial
Boilerplate, 67 D
UKE L.J. 1, 3 n.2 (2017) (describing a contractual “black hole” as occurring when a
clause’s original meaning is “lost entirely by the process of repetition and the insertion of random
variations”).
9
See Robert E. Scott, Stephen J. Choi & Mitu Gulati, Contractual Landmines, 41 YALE J. REG.
(forthcoming 2023) (describing contractual landmines as “vague and apparently purposeful changes
to standard language that increases a creditor’s nonpayment risk, coupled with blatant errors in
expression and drafting and a continuing use of inapt terms that were historically imported from
corporate transactions”).
10
For discussions of how boilerplate terms become resistant to change, see Charles J. Goetz &
Robert E. Scott, The Limits of Expanded Choice: An Analysis of the Interactions Between Express and
Implied Contract Terms, 73 C
ALIF. L. REV. 261, 265-73 (1985); Marcel Kahan & Michael Klausner,
Standardization and Innovation in Corporate Contracting, 83 V
A. L. REV. 713, 719 (1997) (describing
how standardized contract terms create learning benets because the terms have been commonly
used); Stephen J. Choi, Robert E. Scott & Mitu Gulati, Revising Boilerplate: A Comparison of Private
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 188 5
We draw the distinction between bespoke contracting and standardized
contracting more sharply in this paper than what we generally observe in
commercial contracting. Reality is much less clear than any stylization
designed to illuminate the dierences between the two contracting practices.
Inevitably, the lines between the two production techniques are blurred. The
best way to understand this distinction, therefore, is to visualize bespoke
contracting and standardized contacti ng as poles of a continuum where many
markets along the continuum exhibit features of both.
In this Article, we examine one such market: M&A contracts that are
transactions that fall between the poles of the continuum described above.
The M&A market often involves large, sophisticated parties with the
resources and, on occasion, the motivation to craft bespoke contracts. The
market also includes a number of repeat players (including private equity
funds and their law rms) that benet from employing standardized terms
across deals that provide both greater certainty than bespoke terms and
reduced transactional costs. In such a market, we posit that parties will value
both the option to employ bespoke terms and the ability to draw upon a pool
of standardized terms. With such a preference, we expect a market structure
that allows for some degree of coordination to develop standardized terms as
well as the freedom for individual actors to employ their own bespoke terms.
The features of the M&A market display such a str ucture.
The lawyers drafting these M&A agreements, and particularly the subset
of pr ivate equity M&A contracts, belong to a network of practitioners that
meet frequently at conferences, often together with the judges who decide
litigated cases, to discuss new developments.
11
These conferences act as focal
points for discussion and coordination over how contract terms should reect
new developments in the law and “best” contracting practices. We use
interviews with market participants as well as data drawn from a random
sample of M&A contracts to determine how and when drafters in this
network respond to novel caselaw developments. As a focal point, the
conferences help encourage a degree of standardization. But individual
attorneys enjoy the freedom and resources (partic ularly from their private
equity clients who will be concerned about individual liability) to design their
own variations on proposed standards.
12
Consequently, the contracts
and Public Company Transactions, 2020 WIS. L. REV. 629, 629-30 [hereinafter Revising
Boilerplate](discussing agency costs and coordination diculties as sources of stickiness in
boilerplate terms).
11
Matthew Jennejohn, Julian Nyarko & Eric Talley, Contractual Evolution, 89 U. CHI. L. REV.
901, 908-09 (2021).
12
See, e.g., Glenn West, Protecting the Private Equity Firm and Its Deal Professionals From the
Obligations of its Acquisition Vehicles and Portfolio Companies, W
EIL GLOB. PRIV. EQUITY BLOG (May
23, 2016), https://privateequity.weil.com/features/protecting-private-equity-rm-deal-
1886 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
produced by this structure are characterized by a mixture of standardized
terms—representations and warrantie s that are market terms used
throughout the industry—as well as bespoke negotiations over terms that
reect new developments in the caselaw (drawn from the Delaware Court of
Chancery where parties typically litigate).
13
Our particular focus is on novel contract doctrines that invite sellers to
erect barriers to buyers claims for rescission based on fraud. The preliminary
evidence we provide is consistent with the hypothesis that the private equity
network deploys an organic, multilevel process that coordinates eorts to
contract over fraud; it is a process that in time produces standardized terms
dealing with fraud that are used throughout the market.
The Article proceeds as follows. Part I sets out the tradeos involved in
contracting in dierent markets in some detail. We rst explain how parties
in thin or bilateral contracting markets optimize the costs of production for
each transaction by adjusting the allocation of costs between the front-end
costs of drafting ex ante agreements and the expected back-end costs of
enforcing those contracts . This bespoke balancing of ex ante and ex
postproduction costs is driven by the degree of uncertainty unique to that
specic conte xt. These eorts to customize the individual contract are costly
but they do yield the most ecient contract for the production cost.
14
But as
markets thicken, traders in multilateral contracting environments can exploit
economies of scale by standardizing the production of the contract terms that
will govern all transactions in the market thereby reducing the transaction
costs of producing customized contract terms.
15
However, market
standardization leads to the ineciencies of boilerplate discussed above:
standardized contract terms resist adaptation to changed conditions.
16
professionals-obligations-acquisition-vehicles-portfolio-companies/ [https://perma.cc/HKX5-
LMPJ] (describing the process for courts to “pierce” the “corporate veil and hold a corporation’s
owners or aliates liable for its actions).
13
See, e.g., Glenn West, Too Much Dynamite: The Non-Recourse and Survival Clauses Are Both
Subject to Delaware’s Built-In Fraud Carve-Out for Intentional Intra-Contr actual Fraud, W
EIL GLOB.
PRIV. EQUITY BLOG (Aug. 24, 2021), https://privateequity.weil.com/glenn-west-musings/too-much-
dynamite-the-non-recourse-and-survival-clauses-are-both-subject-to-delawares-built-in-fraud-
carve-out-for-intentional-intra-contractual-fraud/ [https://perma.cc/PJK9-GCJL] (prescribing
M&A deal terms that are responsive to the recent Delaware Court of Chancery decision in Online
Healthnow, Inc. v. CIP OCL Investments, LLC, 2021 WL 3557857(Del. Ch. Aug. 12, 2021)).
14
See Scott & Triantis, supra note 7, at 836-37 (describing the tradeos between front-end and
back-end drafting of contracts).
15
For discussion, see Mark R. Patterson, Standardization of Standard-Form Contracts:
Competition and Contract Implications, 52 W
M. & MARY L. REV. 327, 331 (2010) (noting that these
common contractual formulations can reduce the need to negotiate new contracts).
16
See supra note 10 (citing sources on the stickiness of boilerplate terms).
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1887
Nevertheless, there is evidence that there are variations in the speed and
nature of adaptation across these markets .
17
In Part II, we frame the hypothesis that lawyers drafting private equity
acquisition contracts are able to respond in a coordinated fashion to new
developments in the law but do so in an “organic fashion that results in
numerous variations driven by individual actors in a multilateral
environment. We use as our template the evolution of contract law over the
past twenty years, as De laware courts invited drafting lawyers to depart from
common law doctrine by contracting over fraud. Initially, as sellers
successfully negotiated for damage caps on their liability, buyers required a
carve-out from this limitation for any claims of fraud. Thereafter, Delaware
courts endorsed no-reliance clauses in which buyers armed that they were
not relying on any claims arising from extra contractual representations made
by sellers’ agents.
18
Subsequently, the Delaware Court of Chancery in ABRY
Partners v. F&W Acquisition armed the market status of the no-reliance
clauses that had become ubiquitous in the interim and also endorsed eorts
by sellers to limit their liability for intra-contractual fraud to evidence of
deliberate, intentional fraud.
19
The question Part II poses, then, is whether
and in what form drafters, individually or as members of a network,
incorporate these novel fraud-limiting provisions into their private equity
acquisition agreements.
Part III tests the coordination hypothesis by positing that the parties to
M&A deals, and private acquisition deals in particular, belong to a network
that facilitates the exchange of information needed to revise standard terms.
20
We explore the possible pathways that drafters in this network use to
transform bespoke eorts to limit fraud claims into standardized boilerplate.
Here we report on interviews with thirty practitioners who are experienced
in M&A deals. We asked our respondents how and in what ways initial eorts
to contract over fraud evolve into market-wide standardized terms. This
17
For a prior examination of this variation, see Revising Boilerplate, supr a note 10.
18
Infra Part II.A.
19
891 A.2d 1032, 1034-35 (Del. Ch. 2006). Since some states continue to follow the common
law prohibition on contracting over fraud, drafters were also urged to amend their governing law
clauses to de signate Delaware as the choice of law for both contract and tort claims in order to
prevent buyers from pursuing their fraud claims in jurisdictions that followed the older common
law rules. See Choi, Gulati & Scott, infra note 43 (discussing governing law clauses).
20
Networks are mechanisms for coordination and cooperation between formally independent
but functionally interdependent entities. For prior work that studies advisory networks as conduits
for information transfer and coordination among deal lawyers, see Kristina Bishop, Matthew
Jennejohn & Cree Jones, Top Ups and “Telephone” 1 (BYU L. Sch. Working Paper, 2022),
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4313301 [https://perma.cc/59HW-MN7K];
Matthew Jennejohn, Julian Nyarko & Eric Talley, Contractual Evolution, 89 U.
CHI. L. REV. 901,
908-09 (2021); Matthew Jennejohn, The Architecture of Contract Innovation, 59 B.C.
L. REV. 71, 73
(2018).
1888 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
evidence suggests that drafters can overcome the collective action problems
that impede ecient contract design by exploiting an informal network that
organizes their loose web of relationships: parties rely on the information
generated in the network to reach a consensus that transforms novel and
initially “bespoke terms into widely accepted “market terms. This focus on
organic coordination conceives of the contracting parties in this world as
members of a commercial network that communicates important information
through several dierent pathways.
In Part IV we present a preliminary quantitative empirical analysis that is
consistent with the claim that multilay ered pathways serve as unique
mechanisms of coordination in the private equity acquisitions market. That
analysis reveals a widespread, if gradual, diusion of fraud carve-outs in the
M&A market, rst in private target transactions and then in public target
deals.
21
The subsequent practice of narrowly dening fraud in the acquisition
agreement—an important step if the full advantage of ABRY is to be
obtained—followed a similar trajectory.
22
Both patterns are consistent with a
coordination process roote d in information sharing within the network, as
opposed to change driven by a single institution or hierarchy in a top-down
process. We then dig deeper into the diusion process, asking what dynamics
within the network appear to drive the adoption of a clause narrowly limiting
the fraud carve-out.
Contrary to what we might have expected based on prior research on other
markets, such as the sovereign bond market,
23
we nd no evidence that a
vanguard of elite law rms leads the adoption of a new contract term. If
anything, it appears that the top advisory rms lagged others in the adoption
of a term that limits the fraud carve-out to intentional fraud.
24
We also nd
evidence that is suggestive of multiple diusion mechanisms—from the
writings of an inuential practitioner to dissemination of market studies by
the American Bar Association’s M&A Subcommittee—operating in
tandem.
25
I. T
HE PRODUCTION OF CON TRACTS IN BOTH THI N AND THICK
MARKETS
In this Part, we describe the pole s of the continuum formed by ecient
design at one pole and ecient production at the other. Ecient design
21
See infra Part IV.A.
22
Id.
23
See Choi & Gulati, Innovation in Boilerplate, infra note 82.
24
Infra Part IV.C.
25
An analysis of the language advisors use in dening fraud reveals heterogeneity that persists
over time, consistent with the impetus for adoption coming from multiple sources. Id.
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1889
occurs in bespoke transactions where parties cost considerations are limited
to optimizing the costs of production for that contract only. Here, the
transaction costs of producing the contract terms are high but may be justied
by the resulting design eciencies. At the other pole we nd the fully
standardized contract, where a thick market produces boilerplate contract
terms that substantially reduce the costs of production so long as parties use
the standard terms. The tradeo is that reliance on these standard terms
necessarily leads to obsolescence and errors that inevitably emerge in the
boilerplate.
A. Bespoke Contracting in Thin Markets
Bespoke transactions are characteristic of thin markets where the actors
are few and scattered, and thus require substantial eorts to design and
produce contracts eciently.
26
Here, the goal is to weigh production costs
against the incentive gains in achieving ecient investment and trade in the
given transaction. The thinness of the market removes any scale economies
from the production process. This leads to parameter specic strategies in
which individual dyads shift costs of production between front-end
transaction costs and back-end enforcement costs in dierent ways. It is the
particular balancing of front-end and back-end costs within each trans action
that optimizes contractual incentives.
27
The particular allocation of costs
between front and back-end in each transaction is driven by the degree of
uncertainty in that economic environment.
28
Thus, when the level of
uncertainty is low, contract designers can anticipate and address (most of) the
future states of the world and specify what should happen in each possible
state.
29
In this case, most of the costs of production are allocated to initial
eorts in negotiating and formulating fully specied contingent contract
terms.
26
Bespoke transactions are tailor-made contracts designed to t the requirements of a single
transaction or transaction type. For discussion, see Ronald J. Gilson, Charles F. Sabel & Robert E.
Scott, Text and Context: Contract Interpretation as Contract Design, 100 C
ORNELL L. REV. 1, 43-44
(2014); see also Alan Schwartz & Joel Watson, The Law and Economics of Costly Contracting, 20 J.L.
ECON. & ORG. 1, 2-5 (2004) (identifying the balancing that occurs between contracting and
renegotiation costs).
27
See Scott & Triantis, Anticipating Litigation, supra note 7, at 817 (“[T]he mix of precise and
vague terms that characterize the typical commercial contract can be framed as the product of a
tradeo that the parties have made in investing in the front end or back end of the contracting
process, based on their particular circumstances.”).
28
Gilson, Sabel & Scott, Text and Context, supra note 26 at 55-57 (“In general, legally
sophisticated parties designing bespoke contracts choose between text and context by trading o the
front-end (or drafting) costs of contracting and the back-end (or enforcement) costs.”).
29
Cf. Scott & Triantis, Anticipating Litigation, supra note 7, at 816 (explaining why parties
sometimes consent to contracts which fail to address various contingencies appropriately).
1890 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
As uncertainty increases, however, eorts to craft bespoke state
contingent contracts come under pressure and parties are motivated to shift
costs to the back-end enforcement process.
30
Here, parties design more
exible relational contracts by using standards governing key terms such as
price, quantity, and eort that delegate ex post discretion to courts.
31
Distribution contracts are an example in this environment of the eciency
advantages of coupling an explicit statement of obligation with a broad ‘best
eorts’ standard that gives a subsequent court discretion over how the
obligation is enforced.
32
Technological change has raised the level of
uncertainty even higher. As a consequence, more complex collaborative
agreements have emerged that require more creative eorts to shift additional
resources to the back end.
33
In these collaborative agreements, the few formal
elements of the contract are designed to facilitate the growth of trust that, in
turn, will regulate the substantive elements of the parties’ relationship. Here,
drafters create a formal governance structure designed to induce complex
cooperative behaviors that are braided with a few explicit obligations.
34
In all of these bespoke settings, where resource allocation choice s are
inuenced primarily by the level of uncertainty, the costs of production are
assessed only by reference to the incentive gains produced in that particular
transaction. An appropriate analogy is the relationship between the costs of
crafting a beautiful piece of furniture by hand and the value derived from its
sale to an appreciative buyer. But those considerations are inapt once the
market for furniture of this style increases and the cabinetmaker now
contemplates making many sales of similarly designed pieces to many buyers.
When markets thicken and scale economies can be realized—both in th e
30
Gilson, Sabel & Scott, Te xt and Context, supra note 26, at 56-57 (“[T]he greater the
uncertainty associated with a contract—the more dicult for the contracting parties to specify all
the future states of the world in which the contract will have to be performed . . .—the more the
contracting parties confront a dilemma.”).
31
Allowing exibility (or discretion) in relational contracts saves parties the transaction costs
from continually having to update or renegotiate price or quantity in light of changed circumstances.
In long-term procurement agreements, for example, an uncertain future motivates the parties to
expend substantial design eorts on contextualized standards that permit quantity and price to be
adjusted as circumstances change over time. See Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, The Common Law
of Contract and the Default Rule Project, 102 V
A. L. REV. 1523, 1530 n.19 (2016) (describing how default
standards shift costs from the front to the back end of the contracting process).
32
See Scott & Triantis, supra note 7, at 85156 (discussing how parties contextualize standards
to t their circumstances).
33
For discussion of these collaborative contracts and contracting for innovation, see generally
Ronald J. Gilson, Charles F. Sabel & Robert E. Scott, Contracting for Innovation: Vertical
Disintegration and Interrm Collabor ation, 109 C
OLUM. L. REV. 431 (2009).
34
For a discussion of the interplay between the formal governance structure and the informal
bonds of trust that it generates through iterative exchanges of information between the parties, see
generally Ronald J. Gilson, Charles F. Sabel & Robert E. Scott, Braiding: The Interaction of Formal
and Informal Contracting in Theory, Practice, and Doctrine, 110 C
OLUM. L. REV. 1377 (2010).
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1891
underlying economic good and in the contract that regulates the trade—the
cost of producing any given contract becomes economically relevant. It is in
these multilateral contracting environments that production eciencies can
undermine ecient design.
B. Production Eciencies in Thick Markets
Producing contracts more eciently in large multilateral markets such as
sovereign and corporate debt creates value that is shared among the market
participants. Contract production eciencies result pr imarily from th e
standardization of contract terms that are enabled by economies of scale.
35
In
these thick markets where there is scale in the production of an economic
good, standardized contract terms facilitate the scaling of the associated
contracts as well. Beyond the savings in transaction costs, standardized terms
bring to bear a collective wisdom and experience of ways to avoid mistakes in
designing terms.
36
Standardized terms also reduce learning costs by providing
a uniform system of communication: repetition reduces the cost that others
must expend in learning the meaning of the clause.
37
Standardization in the production of boilerplate is, however, a double-
edged sword: the eciencies that reduce the costs of producing contracts also
make it costly for parties to deviate from the standard and are the very source
of the contracts design ineciencies. Standard-form contract terms are
dierent from the optimal terms in a bespoke commercial contract. The
certainty that standardization imparts to the market limits the capacity of
contract drafters in large and liquid markets to draft vague standards designed
to grant discretion to later courts to enforce contractual rights. Here, drafters
are functionally incapable of shifting the costs of production fr om the front
end of the contracting process to the back end as they do when designing
35
See Robert E. Scott, The Paradox of Contracting in Markets, 83 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 71,
72-73 (2020) (“[A]s markets thicken, traders can exploit economies of scale in multilateral contracting
markets by standardizing the production of the contracts that govern the exchange transaction.”).
36
The unique benets of standardization derive from the process by which standard
formulations of terms evolve and gain a distinct, recognized, and consistent meaning within the
market. This evolutionary process tests combinations of terms for dangerous but latent defects. Over
time, the consequences of standard formulations are observable over a wide range of transactions,
permitting the removal of ambiguities and inconsistencies. Goetz & Scott, supra note 10, at 265-73.
In this way, mature standardized terms become validated by experience and are therefore safer than
new and innovative formulations of terms. See T
INA L. STARK, NEGOTIATING AND DRAFTING
CONTRACT BOILERPLATE § 1.02 (2003) (observing that provisions that have been used repeatedly
develop a “hallowed status” and have now been blessed).
37
Marcel Kahan & Michael Klausner, Standardization and Innovation in Corporate Contracting,
83 V
A. L. REV. 713, 719 (1997) (describing that standardized contract terms create learning benets
because the terms have been commonly used).
1892 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
bespoke contracts in bilateral markets.
38
This limitation puts even more
pressure on drafters in these markets to rely on fully specied terms that will
motivate parties to invest and trade eciently.
Unfortunately, the very elements of xed and unchanging meaning that
make standardized terms attractive are the same elements that can contribute
to the erosion of that meaning over time. The problem is obsolescence;
standardized terms are sticky and thus slow to change in response to changes
in contract law and doctrine.
39
Indeed, obsolete standardized terms in
boilerplate contracts may over time lose any recoverable meaning, creating
what we refer to as a contractual black hole.
40
Over time, some standardized
terms are used so consistently that they lose meaning; they are used simply
because ever yone uses them.
41
Matters get worse if legal jargon is overlaid on
standard linguistic formulations.
42
Drafters working with standard-form
language that has been repeated by rote for many years often lack
understanding of the contemporary purpose(s) served by the boilerplate
terms. Drafting marginal modications to t the goals of a transaction while
38
An illustration of the diculty of drafting standards in multilateral markets for courts to
interpret ex post is the largely futile eorts of parties seeking to have courts enforce the ubiquitous
material adverse change clause (MAC) in merger and acquisition contracts. The MAC is designed
as a standard term that will permit the acquirer to abandon the merger in light of specied events
that occur after signing but before the deal closes. Eric L. Talley, On Uncertainty, Ambiguity, and
Contractual Conditions, 34 D
EL. J. CORP. L. 755, 760-61 (2009)(discussing the purpose and design of
the modern Material Adverse Eect provision). Delaware courts rarely nd a material adverse
change sucient to trigger a MAC and justify the acquirer backing out of a merger deal. See, e.g.,
In re IBP, Inc. S’holders Litig., 789 A.2d 14 (Del. Ch. 2001 )(declining to allow a buyer to terminate
a transaction on the basis of an alleged Material Adverse Eect); Hexion Specialty Chems., Inc. v.
Huntsman Corp., 965 A.2d 715, 722 (Del. Ch. 2008)(granting a request for specic performance,
nding that there had not been a MAC); Frontier Oil v. Holly Corp., No. CIV.A. 20502, 2005 WL
1039027, at *37 (Del. Ch. Apr. 29, 2005)(determining that nondisclosure of threatened litigation,
which had not been proved likely to create a Material Ad verse Eect, was not a breach of warranties
and representations sucient to permit nonperformance), judgment entered sub nom., Frontier Oil
Corp. v. Holly Corp. (Del. Ch. 2005); Channel Medsystems, Inc. v. Bos. Sci. Corp., No. CV 2018-
0673-AGB, 2019 WL 6896462, at *1 (Del. Ch. Dec. 18, 2019), judgment entered, 2019 WL 7293896
(Del. Ch. Dec. 26, 2019)(nding that the inaccuracy of statements due to fraud had not been proved
to rise to the level of a MAE); AB Stable VIII LLC v. Maps Hotels & Resorts One LLC, No. CV
2020-0310-JTL, 2020 WL 7024929, at *1-2 (Del. Ch. Nov. 30, 2020), judgment entered 2021 WL
426242, (Del. Ch. Feb. 5, 2021), and a ’d, 268 A.3d 198 (Del. 2021) (nding no MAE). The Court
of Chancery’s opinion in Akorn, Inc. v. Fresenius Kabi AG, 198 A.3d 724 (Table), 2018 WL 6427 137,
at *1 (Del. 2018) stands out as the sole exception to that long line of recent cases. The eect of courts
reluctance to nd a MAC is that the MAC clause functionally becomes a standardized “no MAC”
term in the contract.
39
See supra note 10 (citing sources on the stickiness of boilerplate terms).
40
For discussion on this topic, see Choi, Gulati & Scott, supra note 3, at 3-4 n.2.
41
See Goetz & Scott, supra note 10, at 288-89 (explaining that “rote usage” of contract language
corrupts its meaning so as to ultimately become meaningless).
42
Id.
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1893
ignorant of the contemporary function of the contract’s boilerplate terms may
lead to errors in an eort to clarify the boilerplate.
43
C. The Collective Action Problem and the Role of the M&A Network
Given the important role that standardization plays in replicating
boilerplate terms in tens of thousands of commercial contracts in large
multilateral markets, and the non-trivial possibility that a court may err in
interpreting terms that are obsolete or encrusted with legal jargon, parties
have incentives in these markets to ensure that their standardized contract
terms are continually revised. Updating standard terms in these thick markets
is essential to preserving a common and contemporary meaning. Despite these
incentives, there is evidence that parties in multilateral markets often fail to
react to changes in contract law and doctrine and fail readily to convert
standardized terms into new and ecient formulations.
44
Inertia results from
costs that collectively deter an individual participant from revising the
standard terms. Participants in multilateral markets express a strong
preference for a standard package of terms because revision increases the
learning costs for potential traders.
45
Since the production of network
externalities is a primary value of standardized contracts, it follows that
standardized contract terms will be slow to change even after market
participants identify costly errors and ambiguities.
46
Meanwhile, the
ineciencies caused by linguistically obscure or obsolete boilerplate may not
be fully priced by the market.
47
There is a solution to the impediments that prevent individual traders in
large, multilateral markets from revising obsolete terms. Consider the
sovereign bond market as an example; if the market participants acted
together, they could coordi nate to create a network of traders who collectively
43
See Stephen J. Choi, Mitu Gulati & Robert E. Scott, Variation in Boilerplate: Rational Design
or Random Mutation?, 20 A
M. L. & ECON. REV. 1, 41 (2017) (describing this phenomenon in the case
of the pari passu clause in sovereign bonds); see also Stephen J. Choi, Robert E. Scott & Mitu Gulati,
Investigating the Contract Production Process, 16 C
AP. MKTS. L.J. 414, 425 (2021) (describing the impact
of lawyerly tinkering with the standard governing law clause).
44
See Variation in Boilerplate: Rational Design or Random Mutation?, supra note 43, at 41
(“Contract clauses that no one understands can [often] become part of the standard template, and
variations among those clauses that are largely meaningless can arise and even grow in usage.”).
45
See Anna Gelpern, Mitu Gulati & Jeromin Zettelmeyer, If Boilerplate Could Talk: The Work
of Standard Terms in Sovereign Bond Contracts, 44 L
AW & SOC. INQUIRY 617, 626-27 (2019)
(describing the preference for standard terms because they are simple and bring a sense of
legitimacy). This preference suggests that contract terms are more endogenous than is typically
assumed in models of contract where individual purchasers and sellers come to the market with their
individual preferences that are independent of those of other traders.
46
For discussion about this phenomenon, see Kahan & Klausner, supra note 37, at 727-29.
47
For a discussion of the diculty in pricing terms in these markets, see Contractual Landmines,
supra note 9, at 40 n.100.
1894 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
advance a new standard market term with a clear meaning and purpose. But
it is challenging in large multilateral markets to create a functioning network
that can coordinate the eorts of all the participants. In a recent study, we
compared the speed with which obsolete terms are revised in M&A
transactions with analogous sovereign and corporate bond contracts.
48
In each
market, the contracts contained a standard No Recourse clause that had
become obsolete over time. This left investors vulnerable to liability claims
based on tort and other equitable theories.
49
The emerging case law should
have motivated parties in all three markets to modify the obsolete clause to
better protect against these non-contractual claims.
50
The modication would
have been easy to implement. Yet the vast majority of the corporate and
sovereign bond contracts continued to use the obsolete No Recourse clause,
largely unchanged from previous decades, conrming the diculty of
revising terms in these markets.
51
By contrast, over fty percent of the private
M&A deal contr acts were revised following a series of industry meetings
discussing the changes in the caselaw.
52
Indeed, in the deals done by the top
ve law rms in the industry, every private deal contract was revised.
53
Parties in the private M&A deal market were better able to coordinate on
a standard revision via a combination of industry meetings and leadership
from the top law rms. By coalescing around a standard revision to the No
Recour se clause, the top rms overcame the reluctance of other drafters to
change the language unilaterally. In contrast, corporate and sovereign bond
contracts continued to use the obsolete No Recourse term, despite the
litigation risk.
54
These ndings suggest that there are variations across
markets both in the capacity for coordination and the willingness of key actors
to experiment with customized revisions.
The comparison between the M&A market and the bond market
highlights potential dierences between the two market types. In the M&A
market, and particularly its private deal variant, contracting parties have
devised mechanisms that support inter-party collaborations.
55
In contrast, the
48
See generally Revising Boilerplate, supra note 10.
49
Id. at 633-34.
50
Id. at 634-35.
51
Id. at 649.
52
Id. at 648.
53
See id. at 652 (noting that after 2014 every single top rm used the revised contract clause).
54
Id.
55
The market for derivatives is an example of parties devising a mechanism that functions to
update contract terms in light of chang ed conditions. The International Swaps and Derivatives
Association (ISDA) frequently updates the ISDA Master Contract. The ISDA Determination
Committees are a central authority to make ocial, binding determinations regarding the existence
of “credit events“ and “succession events” (such as mergers), which may trigger obligations under
a credit default swap contract. For discussion of the history of the formation of the derivatives
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 189 5
sovereign and corporate bond markets appear to lack a systematic means of
inducing necessary changes in contract language.
In the following Parts, we test the hypothesis that parties in the smaller
M&A deal market can function as mutual cooperators in a network that
facilitates revisions in standardized contract terms. As the basis for this
inquiry we rst turn in Part II to a salient development in contemporary
contract law: the willingness of De laware courts to depart from older common
law doctrine by permitting contracting parties to contract over fraud and
thereby limit their exposure to fraud claims.
II. C
ONTRACTING OVER FRAUD: I NCORPO RATING NEW L AW INTO
STANDARD TERMS
In this Part, we frame a test of how and to what extent the M&A market
is able to coordinate on contract revisions that respond to legal change. We
focus particularly on the responses by private M&A deal drafters to the
evolving changes in the ability of parties to contract over fraud.
A. From No-Reliance Clauses to the Fraud Carve-Out
At common law, eorts by commercial parties to contract over fraud were
strictly policed. Courts routinely held that claims of fraud were an exception
to the parol evidence rule even where the contract contained a merger clause
that most common law courts held was conclusive evidence that the written
agreement was fully integrated and contained all the terms of the parties’
agreement.
56
The rst crack on this bulwark occurred in New York in Danann
Realty v. Harris in 1959.
57
The contract in Danann Realty contained the
following language:
The Seller has not made and does not make any representations as to the
physical condition, rents, leases, expenses, operation or any other matter or
thing aecting or related to the aforesaid premises, except as herein
specically set forth, and the Purchaser hereby expressly acknowledges that . . .
network, see Jerey B. Golden, Setting Standards in the Evolution of Swap Documentation, 13 INTL
FIN. L. REV. 18, 18-19(1994); M. Konrad Borowicz, Contracts as Regulation: The ISDA Master
Agreement, 16 CAP. MKTS. L.J. 72, 73-75 (2021).
56
See generally Stephen F. Ross & Daniel Trannen, The Modern Parol Evidence Rule and Its
Implications for New Textualist Statutory Interpretation, 87 G
EO. L.J. 195 (1995) (discussing the history
of the parol evidence rule).
57
Danann Realty Corp. v. Harris, 157 N.E.2d 597, 598 (N.Y. 1959) (emphasis added) (denying
a claim that the plainti was induced to enter into the contract based on false oral statements).
1896 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
neither party [is] relying upon any statement or representation, not embodied in
this contract, made by the other.
58
The New York Court of Appeals held that this clause, now known as a
“No-Reliance” provision, was enforceable to prevent the lessor from claiming
fraudulent misrepresentations regarding the expenses for maintaining the
leased property made by agents of the seller. The New York court emphasized
that the clause was clear and specically disclaimed any reliance on the
representations at issue in the case.
59
In the years following Danann Realty,
courts in New York consistently armed the ability of contracting parties to
deploy the No-Reliance clause to bar claims of fraud for extra-contractual
representations by agents of the seller.
60
Over time, the ability of parties to contract over fraud was recognized in
other jurisdictions as well. Thus, in 2003, the Delaware Chancery Court in
H-M Wexford LLC v. Encorp, Inc. armed the enforceability of an explicit
and clear No-Reliance cl ause to exclude evidence of extra contractual
misrepresentations.
61
The question of how far parties to agreements governed by Delaware law
could contract over fraud became more salient when buyers in private equity
acquisition agreements began in the early 2000s to insist on a “fraud carve-
out.
62
The fraud carve- out originated in response to private equity deals
growing use of indemnication provisions, which limit an acquirer’s remedies
(generally to ten to twenty percent of the contract price), in the event a seller
breaches certain representations regarding the qualities of the target
company. While buyers came to accept those seller-friendly indemnication
terms, they in turn negotiated for fraud carve-outs as exceptions that retained
58
Id.
59
Id. at 600.
60
ROBERT E. SCOTT & JODY S. KRAUS, CONTRACT LAW AND THEORY 433-35 (5th ed.
2013).
61
832 A.2d. 129, 142-43 (Del. Ch. 2003).
62
One seasoned partner explained that the emergence of the fraud carve out could be traced
to the rise of indemnication provisions in private equity deals:
People started to say a buyer shouldn’t have all the remedies available at common law in the event of
a breach, and so the indemnication regime began to emerge. Indemnication was supposed to be the
sole remedy . . . . At some point, buyers said, I’m ne with limiting my ability to recover for a breach
of the seller’s reps to a 10 percent limitation of the purchase price, but if you literally lie to me, and I
rely on that to my detriment, then that shouldn’t be subject to the cap.’ Sellers would say, ‘Sure I can
agree to that, because the law doesn’t allow me to limit my liability for fraud. That’s the start of the
fraud carve out.
Zoom Interview with Anonymous Source Thirteen (Dec. 4, 2022).
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1897
a broader range of remedies for a buyer in the event the seller was found to
have committed fraud in the transaction.
63
From this perspective, the fraud carve-out was one side of a swinging
pendulum. Seller s’ desire for nality and a clean break upon the sale of a
company led to increasing use of indemnication provisions, which
circumscribed buyers remedies to a certain percentage of the purchase price,
among other limitations.
64
The fraud carve-out was the buyers reaction: they
were willing to swallow the limitations the indemnication regime imposed
on their potential recovery, but not when the seller had defrauded them.
65
The fraud carve-out has now been used in acquisition agreements for at
least two decades. These carve-outs can appear in multiple places in a private
equity acquisition contract, most commonly in the indemnication and
damages-cap provisions.
66
They have a simple structure. Whatever the
primary clause provides, typically a limitation on the type or quantity of
damages, the fraud carve-out species that the limitation does not apply if
the party in question (typically the seller) commits fraud.
67
But this led to
the question: what do the parties mean by fraud given its numerous and
varied meanings across jurisdictions?
68
If bound by the laws of a jurisdiction
with an expansive view of fraud, sellers could be subject to a much greater
liability than they had anticipated. Could sellers contract for a specic (and
limited) fraud liability at the outset? The Delaware courts, understanding this
concern in the private equity industry, said yes.
69
B. ABRY Partners: From the Fraud Carve-Out to Limited Fraud Clauses
The subsequent evolution of the fraud carve-out accelerated when the
Delaware Court of Chancery decided ABRY Partners v. F&W Acquisition in
2006. The issue posed was whether the parties could contract out of fraud
liability for statements made both within the contract (that is, as part of the
representations and warranties) and outside the contract (informal statements
about the company made by the sellers or their agents in the course of
negotiations or due diligence).
63
Id.
64
Id.
65
Id.
66
See Sarah McLean & Sarah Nealis, Fraud Carve-Out Provisions for M&A Agreements,
E
NERGY L. ADVISOR (Institute Energy L., Plano, Tex.), Oct. 2018 (“One of the most heavily
negotiated provisions of a private M&A transaction agreement is the indemnication
provision . . . commonly referred to as ‘fraud carve-outs.’”).
67
Id.
68
Glenn West, The Pesky Little Thing Called Fraud, 69 BUS. LAW. 1049, 1052 (2014).
69
See, e.g., H-M Wexford LLC v. Encorp Inc., 832 A.2d. 129, 140 (Del. Ch. 2003) (concluding
the parties can contract around fraud).
1898 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
Vice Chancellor Strine, while acknowledging the prior legal regime that
strongly disfavored parties contracting out of fraud liability, moved Delaware
law in a more “contractarian” direction.
70
He rst armed the general market
acceptance of No-Reliance clauses in the acquisitions world. The No-Reliance
clause, however, only applied to extra-contractual representations. Strine
then explained that, while parties still could not contract out of fraud liability
for representations and warranties in the contract, they could limit their fraud
liability for intra-contractual misrepresentations by specifying that the fraud
carve-out only applied to deliberate or intentional misrepresentations. Such
an exclusion would then be eective to eliminate claims based on reckless or
negligent misstatements.
71
As noted in Part II, our pr ior work compared the speed with which
obsolete No Recourse terms are revised in M&A transactions (private and
public) with public company bond issues.
72
Based on that earlier study, we
would expect the M&A market, and particularly its private equity subset, to
follow Strine’s invitation to precisely dene the fraud carve-out in order to
limit its eect to intentional fraud only. For the current project, the question
was not whether the market would respond by producing a “Limited Fraud”
clause, but rather (1) how quickly did it respond and (2) what was the
mechanism that propelled coordination among dierent parties to agree on a
Limited Fraud carve-out as a standardized term?
73
70
For Judge Strine’s own description of what ABRY did, see University of Virginia Law School,
Judge Leo Strine Jr. on Contracts Law,
YOUTUBE (Nov . 30, 2021),
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=FEUHP9XmuLI [https://perma.cc/45KC-X4P 5].
71
Strine subsequently provided an account of how the fraud carve out emerged. He placed the
fraud carve out within a broader evolution of M&A deal architecture, which included no-reliance
provisions, variations in the common law of fraud by jurisdiction, and the emergence of
representations and warranties insurance for private target M&A deals:
“Originally it wasn’t really sure how reliable the no-reliance clause [in an acquisition agreement] was
. . . . It wasn’t really sure that you could even conne the statements on which people could sue. People
got more comfortable with that. [Second], fraud is also not a self-dening term in the common law
. . . . Over time there’s been much more expansion of the concept of misrepresentation to cover things
like negligent misrepresentation and so-called equitable fraud, which is essentially a statement by a
duciary. And so I think part of this fraud exception also came with the need to dene the state of
mind of the statement more precisely. And [nally] there’s also this emergence of an insurance product
here . . . essentially to ensure against the risk of misstatements, but I think primarily designed to cover
the indemnity bucket . . . . So I think what’s developed is to have a strong no reliance cause that you
can insist on if you’re a seller, an indemnity basket for non-scienter breaches of reps and warranties
that are found out, but with a fraud exception, with a scienter denition that allows for recovery if you
can prove, essentially, intentional misstatement that caused harm. Id.
72
Revising Boilerplate, supra note 10, at 633 (examining the progression of these clauses by asking
whether it was caused by “exogenous shocks”).
73
But even if drafters were able to coordinate on a standard No-R eliance clause and a Limited
Fraud carve out, a further legal challenge emerged that motivated even more revisions to the basic
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1899
We turn now in Parts III and IV to examine both the speed and the several
pathways by which parties in the public and private variants of the M&A
network coordinated on standardizing the No-Reliance clause and the
Limited Fraud carve-out in order to eectively contract over fraud within the
space created by the recent changes in the contract law of De laware.
III. U
NPAC KING THE NETWORK
Commercial networks provide parties in multilateral markets with
cognitive resources and frameworks for addressing coordination problems.
74
Parties in these thick markets have limited information about the universe of
possible partners. It follows that it is worthwhile to search for potential
partners who know solutions a single party could not reach alone.
75
It is
therefore appropriate to conceive of the diverse contracting parties in the
private equity acquisition subset of the M&A market as members of a
network of collaborators. All of the participants in the market stand to be
harmed by the ineciencies of standardization, yet no single party can update
standard terms as conditions change or adjust to aberrant judicial
interpretations of ossied boilerplate. By participating in a network, the
parties in multilateral markets can collectively ameliorate these ineciencies.
To evaluate the nature and eect of the private equity network, we
interviewed thirty practitioners with experience in M&A deals. We rst note
the unique relationship this network has to the legal system in the M&A
context studied here. Unlike in other markets, where it is not unusual to nd
a disconnec t between highly specialized market participants and generalist
acquisition agreement. No-Reliance clauses and Limited Fraud clauses are not universally
enforceable. A number of states—particularly California and Massachusetts—decline to enforce
provisions that purport to eliminate fraud claims by contract. Glenn D. West & W. Benton Lewis,
Jr., Contracting to Avoid Extra-Contractual Liability—Can Your Contractual Deal Ever Really Be the
“Entire” Deal?, 100 B
US. LAW. 999, 1024-25 (2009). In several cases, buyers claimed that a governing
law clause designating Delaware law as the basis for evaluating claims under the contract did not
apply to claims for fraud that were grounded in tort rather than contract.
74
See Lisa Bernstein, Beyond Relational Contracts: Social Capital and Network Governance in
Procurement Contracts, 7 J.
LEGAL ANALYSIS 561, 563 (2016) (noting the power of “network
governance” to empower the enforcement of contractual duties).
75
Networks that form to obtain information about potential partners, including most famously
the biotech collaborations in Silicon Valley, have been studied by organizational sociologists. See,
e.g., Walter W. Powell, Kenneth Koput & Laurel Smith-Doerr, Inter-organizational Collaboration and
the Locus of Innovation: Networks of Learning in Biotechnology, 41
ADMIN. SCI. Q. 116, 119 (1996) (“We
argue that when knowledge is broadly distributed and brings a competitive advantage, the locus of
innovation is found in a network of interorganizational relationship.”); Walter W. Powell, Inter-
Organizational Collaborati on in the Biotechnology Industry, 152 J.
INST. & THEORETICAL ECON. 197,
198 (1996)(analyzing the eects that institutional de signs can have on increasing cooperation).
1900 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
courts, the Delaware Court of Chancery is embedded within the M&A
ecosystem.
76
One respondent explained,
You have to understand. Unlike perhaps in other contexts, such as the federal
courts in New York, things are dierent in Delaware. The judges in the
Delaware courts are an integral part of the legal community. They listen to
the concerns of the lawyers, go to their conferences, and answer questions
about the direction of the law. Federal judges in New York do not do this. It
is rare that you will get a real shock in a Delaware case—these judges are all
experienced and careful lawyers. They think hard about what is best for the
market. Judge Strine, who wrote ABRY, prided himself in understanding the
bar and what was needed. I think that that’s true of the other judges too.
77
The Court of Chancery alone is not the sole coordinating institution in
the M&A market. As reported in the empirical analysis below, the ABRY
opinion, standing alone, was insucient to spark swift and comprehensive
adoption of fraud carve- outs and Limited Fraud denitions in private equity
acquisition agreements. Nor does the private bar operate wholly divorced
from the bench when periodic judic ial interventions make a mess of things.
Rather, the judiciary and advisory network work hand-in-glove, the former
seeking to anticipate the latter, and the latter translating the former’s
decisions into practice.
The Court of Chancery’s place in that ecosystem is visible due to its public
status, but the precise way that the advisory netw ork facilitates coordination
among market participants is less clear. Our prior work suggests several
dierent mechanisms that a lawyer network could possibly deploy to
coordinate needed changes in the standard acquisition contract.
78
One
possibility is the capacity of the leading law rms in the industry to serve as
the “spider in the web”—a governing structure or hierarchy that functions as
an agent of coordination.
79
Another coordinating factor could be the inuence
of a voluntary “spider such a leading lawyer who uses their voice to inuence
change. A third avenue of coordination is the evolutionary process of
learning. This process proceeds from the individual level of deal partners
76
See William Savitt, The Genius of the Modern Chancery System, 2012 COLUM. BUS. L. REV.
570, 570-71 (2012) (arguing that the De laware Court of Chancery’s circumscribed jurisdiction and
deep connection to a specialized bar has allowed it to play a leading role in U.S. corporate
governance).
77
Zoom Interview with Anonymous Source Thirteen (Dec. 4, 2022).
78
Revising Boilerplate, supra note 10, at 633.
79
The evidence of the role of the ve leading law rms motivating coordination over changes
to the No Recourse clause in private equity suggests this possibility. See Revising Boilerplate, supra
note 10, at 651-53. The conception of the spider in the network web was introduced in Ariel Porat &
Robert E. Scott, Can Restitution Save Fragile Spiderless Networks?, 8 H
ARV. BUS. L. REV. 1 , 3 (2018)
(contending that a controlling relationship in the center of a network dictates its success).
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1901
teaching each other during bespoke negotiations to the group level of
collective engagement in conferences and bar meetings between drafters and
the judges who rule on litigated cases.
To aid in identifying the likely pathway(s) to coordination, we explained
to our experts that we were interested in understanding the evolution of
standardization of terms relevant to contracting over fraud. We asked (1) what
impediments might explain the time lag betw een bespoke eorts to contract
over fr aud and the standardization of those changes in the market contract,
and (2) what factors were most likely to aect the speed of a successful
coordination on new clauses.
80
We report below on the responses.
A. Leading Law Firms as a Spider
Our prior study of changes to the No Recourse clause found that
coordination in the market occurred among the ve leading law rms who
had the largest share of the private equity acquisitions market. This nding
suggests that perhaps these law rms assumed a special responsibility to
function as the spider in the network web. Thus, even if the pr ivate
acquisition market lacks an obvious controlling entity or hierarchy (such as
the way the ISDA Determination Committees function in the derivatives
market),
81
drafters in these leading law rms could nonetheless work together
to coordinate changes in response to new legal developments.
82
By acting as
rst movers, they could provide key information to others in the market
regarding the eciency benets of the new contract terms. Moreover, by
being the rst drafters in the market to design new terms, the design costs
for subsequent drafters would be measurably reduced. Our respondents,
however, rejected the prediction that we would see particular law rms as
leading the move to a new contractual standard. That was simply not how
contract innovation was likely to spread in this market. Instead, it was likely
spread through a more organic process, via industry conferences, meetings,
and other collective events.
83
80
Our interviews were generally done over Zoom and typically lasted between a half hour and
an hour. At the start of each conversation, we assured our respondents that nothing they said would
be attr ibuted to them and their identities would be kept condential. We then gave a short
explanation of why we had found the fraud carve out provision and the process of dening it
intriguing. In a handful of cases, we had follow-up conversations by email.
81
See Kahan & Klausner, supra note 10, at 727 (discussing the dierent sources from which
network benets can come).
82
For a similar nding on the eect of leading law rms in coordinating innovation regarding
sovereign bonds, see Stephen J. Choi & Mitu Gulati, Innovation in Boilerplate: An Empirical
Examination of Sovereign Bonds, 53 E
MORY L.J. 930, 948 (2004) (predicting that law rms
experienced with a “large volume” of sovereign bonds can lead the path towards newer terms in
bonds).
83
Zoom Interview with Anonymous Source Thirteen (Dec. 4, 2022).
1902 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
B. The Inuence of the Voluntary Spider
In a pair of articles in the Business Lawyer, the rst in 2009 and the second
in 2014, Glenn West, a pr ivate equity specialist at Weil Gotshal, agged
undened fraud in fraud carve- outs as a persistent issue in pr ivate equity
deals. West’s basic exhortation (gentle in 2009, strident in 2014)
84
was clear.
Sell-side clients were willing to agree to fraud carve-outs from the various
damage cap provisions in their contracts because they understood fraud as
intentional misbehavior and they didn’t plan to engage in such behavior. But
the case law in many jurisdictions did not always match the clients
understanding of fraudulent behavior. Instead, the term “fraud” was
susceptible to a range of meanings beyond intentional misstatements of the
particular private equity seller, including reckless and negligent
misstatement. Moreover, some cour ts showed a willingness to attribute the
misstatements of agents (managers of the company the private equity group
was trying to sell) to the sellers themselves. West proposed a solution: parties
could dene precisely what they meant by fraud in their contracts. In
contractarian jurisdictions, like Delaware and New York, courts would likely
defer to the agreement the parties had voluntarily made.
It is plausible to ask whether West’s two publications in the Business
Lawyer, the preeminent business law publication for U.S. practitioners, were
the key factors motivating the market to coordinate on standard terms for
contracting over fraud.
85
We did not explicitly bring up West’s articles in our
interviews. Instead, we asked what might cause the market to coordinate on
a standard market denition of fraud.
A number of our respondents agged West’s writings as important.
Multiple respondents even urged us to read them in order to better
understand the fraud carve- out issue.
86
That said, no respondent thought the
West articles on their own were capable of causing a move toward a
standardized clause. One respondent wryly observed:
I don’t know many senior lawyers who would actually sit down and read an
academic article. Most don’t even read the important Delaware cases. And
84
West & Lewis, supra note 72 at 1024-25; West, supra note 40.
85
There were also several Delaware cases touching on the fraud carve out issue in the 2013-
2017 period. See ENI Holdings LLC v. KBR Grp. Holdings, LLC, C.A. No . 8075-VCG, 2013 BL
332008, 2013 WL 6186326, at *39-41 (Del. Ch. Nov. 27, 2013) (discussing whether an agreement
carved out claims grounded in fraud from being subject to the contractual limitations period); JCM
Innovation Corp. v. FL Acquisition Holdings, Inc., C.A. No. N15C-10-255 EMD CCLD , 2016 BL
325304, 2016 WL 5793192, at *11 (Del. Super. Ct. Sept. 30, 2016) (“JCM counters that the exclusive
provision expressly carves out ‘claims arising from fraud.’”); EMSI Acquisition Inc. v. Contrarian
Funds LLC, C.A. No. 12648-VCS, at *11-12 (Del. Ch. May 3, 2017) (explaining that an agreement
appeared to carve out claims based on fraud from a section limiting remedies to indemnication).
86
We did not reveal that we knew West or were familiar with West’s work.
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1903
make no mistake; Glenn [West] may be a senior partner at a big rm–but
those articles are academic. You need much more than just a couple of such
[academic] articles for change.
87
In other words, West’s academic writings alone were not the spider in the
network. For change, there needed to be more. Another respondent descr ibed
the dynamic as follows:
Glenn [West] had been telling us to dene fraud for years and we’d all nod
our heads and then just copy the old provisions from the prior deals. But at
some point, and probably after that [2014 Business Lawyer] article, the rhetoric
got ramped up. He and others at the ABA’s M&A meetings began telling us
that we were essentially committing malpractice by failing to dene fraud.
That got people to listen. There may have been something else going on as
well. There had always been the threat that opportunistic claims for fraud
would be made. It might have then happened in a few cases like EMSI.
88
C. The Inuence of Multilevel, Collective Engagement
The evidence suggests that the network lacks a single spider. In that
respect, the M&A world, and particularly its private equity subset, more
closely resembles the sovereign debt market than it does the trade association
networks such as those studied by Lisa Bernstein.
89
But unlike sovereign debt,
there is a practice of information exchange among the leading players in the
M&A/pr ivate equity market.
90
For example, in 2009 the M&A Committee
of the American Bar Association’s Business Law Section began sharing
information about the fraud carve-out issue with practitioners in two ways.
First, the M&A Committee’s Deal Points study,
91
which gives deal lawyers
insight into the current state of market practice, began reporting data on what
fraction of a sample of deals were limiting fraud to intentional actions in their
fraud carve-outs.
92
Practitioners could see in the study the initial uptake in
87
Zoom Interview with Anonymous Source Eighteen (Feb. 26, 2022).
88
Zoom Interview with Anonymous Source Twenty-ve (Feb. 18, 2022).
89
See e.g., Lisa Bernstein, Private Commercial Law in the Cotton Industry: Creating Cooperation
Through Rules, Norms, and Institutions, 99 M
ICH. L. REV. 1724, 1725-25 (2001) (describing the private
legal systems that govern trade association dealings); Lisa Bernstein, Merchant Law in a Modern
Economy, in P
HILOSOPHICAL FOUNDA TIONS OF CONTRACT LAW 246-49 (Gregory Klass et. al.
eds., 2015) (illustrating the transactional practices used in merchant communities).
90
For empirical evidence of this information exchange within the M&A network, see Bishop,
Jennejohn & Jones, supra note 20.
91
Public Company Acquisitions of Private Targets: The Results of the 2009 Deal Points Study, PRAC.
L. (Dec. 4, 2009), https://us.practicallaw.thomsonreuters.com/9-500-9034 [https://perma.cc/RP5A-
4FL5].
92
See id. (providing evidence that the ABA Deal Points Study aects diusion patterns of new
deal terms in the M&A market).
1904 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
fraud denitions. And because this information on the market practice in
dening fraud was reported by the Deal Points study every year since 2009,
drafters could follow the evolution toward standardization of the fraud
denition development in the market over time.
Second, the issue of precisely dening fraud was discussed in the
programming provided at the M&A Committee annual meetings. Beginning
roughly in 2010, West and colleagues began presenting on fraud carve-outs at
industry gatherings of lawyers. They informed their audiences of the issues
and staged mock negotiations to illustrate the bargaining dynamics that might
arise in the design of a fraud carve-out.
93
These presentations contextualized
the raw numbers provided in the Deal Points Studies.
The judiciary stayed involved throughout, though it would not provide
another paradigm shifting treatment of the issue like the original ABRY
decision. The Chancery Court interpreted fraud carve-outs and Limited
Fraud clauses from time to time and applied ABRY with delity.
94
Finally, to
close the circle, the Delaware Supreme Court armed Judge Strine’s ABRY
decision in 2021, citing Glenn West’s 2014 Business Lawyer article.
95
Taken together, we see interventions by both the judiciary and leaders
within the bar woven together. ABRY’s message ratifying the “market status
of the No-Reliance clause was understood by 2006 and the implicit invitation
to draft a Limited Fraud clause was taken up by a few rst movers in be spoke
transactions. Leading practitioners, and in particular, the M&A Committee
amplied Judge Strine’s teaching over time, drawing attention to and
educating deal lawyers about the ABRY decision. All the while, the Delaware
judiciary continued to sound a steady drumbeat in support of respecting
parties freedom to contract over fraud.
96
93
See Zoom Interview with Anonymous Source Thirteen (Dec. 4, 2022) (“At that point, I took
the fraud carve out on the road. I felt like John the Baptist crying in the wilderness to the
unconverted. . . . We created a script for a negotiation [to demonstrate the typical bargaining
dynamic and how to address it].”); Zoom Interview with Anonymous Source Fourteen (Oct. 16,
2021) (“I’ve certainly talked about “fraud carve outs at ABA meetings.”); Interview 26 (Oct. 5, 2022)
(noting the discussion of fraud carve outs at ABA meetings and that “those were really well attended
meetings” where there “were some wake up calls”).
94
See, e.g., Fortis Advisors LLC v. Johnson & Johnson, No. CV 2020-0881-LWW, 2021 WL
5893997, at *7-8 (Del. Ch. Dec. 13, 2021) (analyzing a fraud carve out); EMSI Acquisition, Inc. v.
Contrarian Funds, LLC, No. CV 12648-VCS, 2017 WL 1732369, at *18-24 (Del. Ch. May 3, 2017)
(applying ABRY); Prairie Cap. III, L.P. v. Double E Holding Corp., 132 A.3d 35, 60-61 (Del. Ch.
2015) (using ABRY to analyze fraud).
95
Express Scripts, Inc. v. Bracket Holdings Corp., 248 A.3d 824, 830 (2021).
96
See supra notes 92-93 and accompanying text.
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1905
D. Summary
Our respondents resisted our attempt to nd a single mechanism that
might have produced the coordination that changed the terms for contracting
over fraud. In particular, they resisted the hypothesis that either a group of
leading law rms or a single spider, such as Glenn West or Judge Strine, were
the sole moving factors behind any coordination. As we report in Part IV, the
rate of standardization did increase around the 2015-17 period, but these
participants rejected the claim that changes to standard terms were attributed
to any individual or group. Rather, as one interviewee noted, “mostly this is
about conversations among practitioners in the industry on how best to draft.
These are discussed at the meetings and conferences.”
97
This story is
consistent with the hypothesis that, even in an environment like the M&A
acquisition market that lacks a controlling entity or “spider,” coordination can
proceed in a multilevel organic way. The evolutionary process begins with
individual drafters experimenting with bespoke Limited Fraud clauses but
then the eciency advantages of these revisions are transmitted between
negotiating partners and ultimately through a well-integrated collective of
lawyers and judges. And eventually, through this process, a more standard
product emerges.
IV. E
MPIRICAL DATA AN D ANALYSIS
In this section, we report data on both public and private M&A deals
from the period 2000 to 2020, with the goal of observing when changes to
fraud carve-out clauses began and how coordination on revised clauses was
achieved. For each deal, we collected background variables, such as deal size,
industry type, and the law rms advising on the deal, to determine who were
the rst movers in changing contract terms.
In this case, a decade passed from the time that the ABRY Partners decision
was issued to the point at which contracts were narrowly dening fraud at a
meaningful rate. In 2006, the fraud carve-out provision was itself relatively
new and non-standard—so eorts to craft Limited Fraud cl auses were
similarly uncommon. What the data show is an evolutionary process by which
bespoke terms are negotiated between individual parties to particular deals.
It then takes a half-dozen years or more after these bespoke transactions
97
Zoom Interview with Anonymous Source Fifteen (Feb. 3, 2022). The same respondent also
sent us a typescript of a mock negotiation from one of the industry meetings that they said was
illustrative of how the senior members of the bar tried to persuade their colleagues to better dene
fraud in their contracts.
1906 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
appear for them to emerge as standard terms and for Limited Fraud clauses
to become “market.”
Below, we report on data for contracts from public and private M&A deals
from the period 2000 to 2020. For each year, we searched material contracts
on the SEC’s EDGAR database with the goal of collecting 100 randomly
selected contracts: fty private target deals and fty public deals. Deals were
identied by running searches on Westlaw’s and Bloomberg Law’s respective
EDGA R material contracts databases. The actual number of deals analyzed
for each year occasionally exceeded or fell short of that 100-deal goal for either
of two reasons: (1) from time to time, the actual date that an M&A agreement
was executed diered from the date as reected in the Westlaw or Bloomberg
platform, leading us to reassign the deal to the proper year; or (2) facially
distinct but functionally duplicative agreements were later dropped from the
dataset during the coding process.
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1907
Table 1: Number of Deals By Year
Year Number of Deals Percent
2000 107 5.2
2001 115 5.5
2002 83 4.0
2003 99 4.8
2004 88 4.2
2005 107 5.2
2006 92 4.4
2007 90 4.3
2008 102 4.9
2009 89 4.3
2010 95 4.6
2011 100 4.8
2012 115 5.5
2013 100 4.8
2014 98 4.7
2015 93 4.5
2016 96 4.6
2017 100 4.8
2018 95 4 .6
2019 105 5.1
2020 108 5.2
Total 2,077 100.0
For the contracts that were sampled, we coded each contract for both the
presence of fraud carve-out provisions (it is not unusual for fraud carve-outs
to be used in more than one provision of an acquisition agreement) and
whether fraud was narrowly dened. We also collected information about
each deal such as the identities of the merging parties, the date of execution,
the value of the transaction, the identities of the law rms advising the buyer
and seller, the law chosen to govern the transaction, and the industry sector.
The agreements in our sample are material contracts led with the U.S.
Securities and Exchange Commission, usually on Form 8-K. The SEC hosts
those lings and the underlying material contracts on its EDGAR database,
which we searched using the search functions available on two proprietary
1908 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
databases.
98
Given our source-–lings by SEC registered companies of
“materially” important contracts—our data source is biased. It contains no
private-buyer/private-target deals and it may not contain deals where the
registered company that bears the disclosure obligation has operations so
large that many of its modest-sized mergers are considered immaterial.
In what follows, we report results from the data, starting with the overall
picture on the use of the fraud carve-out and then Limited Fraud provisions.
We then cut the data in terms of the types of fraud denitions and the types
of actors most actively involved in the move towards Limited Fraud terms.
A. The Fraud Carve-Out
Figure 1 below reports the incidence of fraud carve-out provisions in our
data. Overall, these gures show that the clause emerges in the early 2000s
and by 2020 it has become standard.
To construct the variable reported in the gures below, we look across the
M&A agreement to identify the instances where a fraud carve-out appears.
We coded six dierent provisions in each contract where these carve-outs
tend to be found: Indemnication, Exclusive Remedy, Survival, Financing,
Termination, and No Additional Representations. We then track the
incidence of fraud carve-outs in those provisions in two ways.
First, we track the number of deals in our dataset with at least one fraud
carve-out in any of the six provisions listed above. Fraud carve-out incidence
is captur ed as a binary variable, which is set to one if a fraud carve- out appears
in any of the six provisions above (and zero, if not). Figure 1 depicts the
percentage of deals with at least one fraud carve- out. The solid trend line
depicts the percentage of private target transactions and the dotted one
depicts public targets.
98
For 2009 onward, we collected agreements from the EDGAR data reported in Westlaw’s
private target and public target acquisitions databases. For the period prior to that (2000 through
2008), for which Westlaw does not report data, we collected agreements from Bloomberg Law’s
private target and public target acquisitions databases.
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1909
Figure 1: Fraction of Deals with at Least One Fraud Carve-Out
From Figure 1, we observe that fraud carve-outs are more prevalent in
private compared with public deals across our sample period. For all private
deals in our dataset, 57.8% have at least one fraud carve-out compared with
46.0% for public deals (dierence signicant at the 1% condence level).
In our second approach, reported in Figure 2 below, we take a dierent
tack. Since we are interested in the adop tion of the fraud carve-out, we tally
the fraud carve-out’s incidence across all six provisions, rather than using a
binary variable that indicates whether a contract contains at least one fraud
carve-out provision (or not). For example, if there is a fraud carve-out in any
one of the six common provisions in a given contract, we code that as a one.
If there is a fraud carve-out in all six provisions, that is a six. This approach
allows us to track, for instance, the mean number of fraud carve-outs per
agreement in our sample. Over our sample period from 2000 to 2020, the
mean number of fraud carve-out terms for private deals (1.05) is greater than
the mean for public deals (0 .59) and this dierence is signicant at the 1%
condence level.
Figure 2 breaks out the frequency data in terms of public and private deals
by year. Acro ss the 2000 to 2020 period, there is an upward trend in the
number of fraud carve-outs for both public and private deals. In the early
2000s, there is less than 0.5 instances of a fraud carve-out on average in both
public and private deals, corresponding to less than one fraud carve- out in
1910 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
every two deals. By 2020, there are over two fraud carve-outs on average in
private deals and over one fraud carve- out on average in public deals.
Figure 2: Frequency of Fraud Carve-Out Incidence,
Private and Public Target Deals
The greater number of fraud carve-outs in private de als is consistent with
the greater importance of carve-outs (and corresponding Limited Fraud
provisions) for private deals. In the public company world, there is no real
benet to carving out fraud or dening it narrowly. One cannot contract
around whatever fraud standard the federal securities laws impose, nor is
there much risk of stockholders being held liable for the misstatements of
company managers.
99
B. Dening Fraud: The Incidence of Limited Fraud Clauses
We turn now to the eorts to narrowly dene fraud: the “Limited Fraud”
terms. Over our sample period from 2000 to 2020, 17.3% of private deals with
a fr aud carve-out also included a Limited Fraud term. In compar ison, only
99
See 15 U.S.C. § 77(n) (“Any condition, stipulation, or provision binding any person acquiring
any security to waive compliance with any provision of this title or of the rules and regulations of
the Commission shall be void.”); 15 U.S.C. § 78cc(a) (“Any condition, stipulation, or provision
binding any person to waive compliance with any provision of this title or of any rule or regulation
thereunder, or of any rule of a self-regulatory organization, shall be void.”).
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1911
3.7% of public deals with a fraud carve-out contained a Limited Fraud
provision. This dierence is signicant at the 1% condence level.
Figure 3 reports on the incidence of a Limited Fraud term in deals with
at least one fraud carve- out for both the public and private markets by year.
For both markets, we see that only a few deals with a fraud carve-out also
included a Limited Fraud provision until around 2015. From then, with a dip
in 2016, we see a steady growth to the end of the dataset particularly in the
private deal market. That marks about a decade after Judge Strine’s ABRY
decision and eight years after Glenn West’s 2009 Business Lawyer article
urging practitioners to narrowly dene fraud.
100
In terms of proximity in
time, Glenn West’s 2014 Business Lawyer article is the closest to the
acceleration in the rate of adoption of Limited Fraud provisions. In addition,
as mentioned earlier, the ABA’s Deal Points study had started reporting in
2009 the fraction of deals in their sample that contained Limited Fraud
terms.
101
But we cannot tell from the data whether Glenn West’s 2014 article
was an impetus for the shift or whether there was an accumulation of pressure
from ABRY, subsequent Glenn West blog posts on the topic, the ABA Deal
Points studies, and other events such as conferences of M&A lawyers where
the topic was discussed, that accumulated to eect the shift.
100
ABRY Partners v. F&W Acquisition, 891 A.2d 1032 (Del. Ch. 2006); Glenn D. West & W.
Benton Lewis, Jr ., Contracting to Avoid Extra-Contractual Liability—Can Your Contractual Deal Ever
Really Be the “Entire” Deal? 100 B
US. LAWYER 1024-25 (2009).
101
Public Company Acquisitions of Private Targets: The Results of the 2009 Deal Points Study, PRAC.
L. (Dec. 4, 2009), https://us.practicallaw.thomsonreuters.com/9-500-9034 [https://perma.cc/RP5A-
4FL5].
1912 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
Figure 3: Percent of Deals with a Fraud Carve-Out that Include a
Limited Fraud Provision
C. Digging Deeper: Who Moved First and How Fast?
We next test the importance of specic law rms in driving the change in
contracting over fraud. Under one theory of contractual change, for which we
have found evidence elsewhere, top law rms are likely to drive contract
innovation.
102
Temporally, we expect under this theory that change should
occur rst for deals involving a top law rm and then later for deals with
other law rms that follow the example set by the top rms.
103
In the context
of private equity deals, the absence of a Limited Fraud term exposes the se ller
to potentially expansive application of a fraud carve-out. We therefore might
expect that the top seller law rms will push rst for the adoption of a narrow
denition of fraud.
To identify the top seller law rms, we use the Vault 2020 ranking of
private equity law rms.
104
For our top law rms, we select the top 5 rms in
102
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 82, at 988 (describing the incentives of a top law rm to drive
contractual change).
103
Id.
104
Vault uses a peer voting system where associates in the relevant area vote on which the best
law rms are. For details on their methodology, see Best Law Firms by Practice Area, V
AULT,
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1913
the Vault 202 0 ranking: (1) Kirkland & Ellis, (2) Simpson Thacher, (3)
Latham & Watkins, (4) Skadden Arps, and (5) Cravath, Swaine & Moore.
We add Wachtell Lipton, which is the 6th ranked rm in the Vault 2020
ranking, because it is the most frequent seller’s attorney in our dataset. We
call these rms the “Top Seller Law Firms. Table 2 reports on the number
of deals in our dataset for which a Top Seller Law Firm acted as the seller’s
attorney.
Table 2: Top Seller Law Firms
Law Firm
Number of Deals as
Seller Attorne
y
Percent of
Deals
Wachtell Li
p
ton 77 4.5
Skadden Ar
p
s 72 4.2
Latham & Watkins 66 3.8
Kirkland & Ellis 60 3.5
Sim
son Thacher 35 2.0
Cravath, Swaine &
Moore 30 1.7
We compare the overall adoption of a Limited Fraud term for Top Seller
Law Firm and other seller law rm deals. For deals with a fraud carve-out
and a Top Seller Law Firm, only 5.4% of the deals had a Limited Fraud term.
In comparison, for deals with a fraud carve-out and other seller law rms,
11.9% of the deals had a Limited Fraud term. The dierence is signicant at
the 1% condence level. Instead of leading the adoption of Limited Fraud
provisions, Top Seller Law Firms correspond with a lower incidence of these
terms compared with deals with other seller law rms.
As a multivariate test of the probability of a Limited Fraud term, we
estimate the following multinomial logit model. We use deals with a fraud
carve-out but no Limited Fraud term as (0) the base outcome. We estimate
two dierent outcomes from the base outcome in the multinomial logit
model: (1) no fraud carve-out and (2) a fraud carve-out with a Limited Fraud
term. The multinomial logit model includes an indicator variable for whether
a private equity rm is the seller in the deal (Private Equity Seller). The
model also includes indicator variables for the presence of a Top Seller Law
https://rsthand.co/best-companies-to-work-for/law/best-law-rms-in-each-practice-area/private-
equity [https://perma.cc/3SB5-832J] (last visited June 28, 2023). Chambers & Partners provides a
similar ranking of private equity advisors, also based on regular surveys of professionals. See USA -
Nationwide Private Equity: Fund Formation Legal Rankings, C
HAMBERS & PARTNERS (2022),
https://chambers.com/legal-rankings/private-equity-fund-formation-usa-nationwide-5:290:12788:1
[https://perma.cc/VUU5-JP4H].
1914 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
Firm and whether the deal is a public deal (Public). As control variables, we
include the log of the deal value in millions of dollars and indicator variables
for whether the contract includes New York or De laware as the choice of law.
Lastly, the model includes the one-digit SIC industry code for the acquisition
target as Industry Eects.
The model is as follows: Prob(Fraud Carve-Out Outcome)= α + ß
1
Private
Equity Seller
i
+ ß
2
Top Seller Law Firm
i
+ ß
3
Public
i
+ ß
4
ln(Deal Value
i
) +
ß
5
New York
i
+ ß
6
Delaware
i
+ Industry Fixed Eects + ε
i.
Table 3 reports the results of the multinomial logit model.
Table 3: Multinomial Model of the Fraud Carve-Out Term
Base Outcome = Fraud Carve-Out with No Limited Fraud
(1) Outcome =
No Fraud Carve-
Out
(2) Outcome =
Fraud Carve-Out
with Limited Fraud
Private E
q
uit
y
Seller -0.135 0.675
(-0.28) (1.60)
To
p
Seller Law Firm -0.188 -0.587
+
(-1.17) (-1.91)
Public 1.698
**
-2.296
**
(10.43) (-6.72)
ln(Deal Value) -0.252
**
0.235
**
(-6.71) (3.18)
New York -0.656
**
-0.214
(-2.87) (-0.45)
Delaware -0.847
**
0.748
*
(-4.92) (2.09)
Constant 24.60 22.44
(0.00) (0.00)
Industr
y
Eects Yes Yes
N 1419
p
seudo R
2
0.141
z statistics in parenthe ses;
+
p < 0.10,
*
p < 0.05,
**
p < 0.01
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1915
From the multinomial logit model in Table 3, note that the coecient on
Top Seller Law Firm is negative and signicant at the 10% condence level
for the Fraud Carve-Out with Limited Fraud outcome. Top Seller Law Firms
correspond with lower incidences of Limited Fraud provisions in a fraud
carve-out compared with the base outcome of Fraud Carve-Out with No
Limited Fraud. The average marginal eect of a Top Seller Law Firm on the
probability of a Limited Fraud provision compared with the base outcome is
-3.1 percentage points. Note also that public deals have a lower probability of
a Limited Fraud provision in a fraud carve-out compared with the base
outcome of Fraud Carve-Out with No Limited Fraud. The average marginal
eect of a public deal (compared with a private deal) on the probability of a
Limited Fraud provision compared with the base outcome is -15.6 percentage
points. In contrast, public deals have a higher probability of having No Fraud
Carve-Out clause compared with the base outcome of Fraud Carve-Out with
No Limited Fraud. The average marginal eect of a public deal (compared
with a private deal) on the proba bility of No Fraud Carve-Out compared with
the base outcome is 35.6 percentage points.
Even though Top Seller Law Firms do not correspond in general with a
greater level of adoption of a narrow fraud denition within fraud carve- outs,
it is possible that the Top Seller Law Firms were the rst in the market to
adopt Limited Fraud terms, leading other law rms to follow th eir lead. To
assess this rst mover possibility, we report the percentage of deals with a
fraud carve-out that also includes a Limited Fraud term by year for bo th Top
Seller Law Firms and other seller law rms in Fig ure 4.
Figure 4: Percent of De als with a Fraud Carve-Out that Include a Limited
Fraud Denition for Top and Ot her Law Firms
1916 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
Note from Figure 4 that the percent of deals with a fraud carve-out that
also includes a Limited Fraud denition in 2020 is greater for the Top Seller
Law Firm (61.1%) when compared with other seller law rms’ driven deals
(52.7%). However, in 2015 and 2016, the two years immediately following
Glenn West’s August 2014 Business Lawyer article, none of the private equity
deals with a Top Seller Law Firm that employed a fraud carve-out had a
Limited Fraud denition. In contrast, the law rms that appeared to lead the
adoption of a Limited Fraud denition were the other law rms in 2015
(11.8%) and in 2016 (5.1%). Rather than being the leaders, the Top Seller Law
Firms follow other rms, adopting Limited Fraud denitions more widely
than other rms only after Limited Fraud denitions became adopted in a
majority of fraud carve-out provisions.
Perhaps the mechanism of change in this industry is not through the top
law rms. Instead, the mechanism could be a single spider—Glenn West
himself. We do not have data on the specic deals involving Glen n West.
However, we can identify those deals where Glenn West’s law rm, Weil
Gotshal, was the seller’s attorney. For deals with a fraud carve-out and Weil
Gotshal as the seller’s law rm, 9.1% of the deals had a Limited Fraud
denition. In comparison, for deals with a fraud carve-out and other seller
law rms, 11.7% of the deals had a fraud carve-out. If anything, Weil Gotshal
corresponds to an overall lower incidence of a Limited Fraud denition in the
fraud carve-out. The dierence in any case is not statistically signicant. We
re-estimated the multinomial logit model in Table 2 above replacing Top
Seller Law Firm with an indicator variable for Weil Gotshal. Unreported, the
coecient on Weil Gotshal is not signicantly dierent from zero for either
the No Fraud Carve-Out or Fraud Carve- Out with Limited Fraud outcomes
in the model. Looking at the timing of the use of a fraud denition when
Weil Gotshal was the seller’s attorney, a Limited Fraud denition was used
only once in our dataset in a public deal in 2014. For the subsequent eight
deals with a fraud carve-out that had Weil Gotshal as the seller’s attorney
after 2014, none of these deals had a Limited Fraud provision. We take this
as inconsistent with Weil Gotshal leading the adoption of Limited Fraud
clauses for the market to use as an example.
D. Deeper Still: Variation in Limited Fraud Provisions
What drives change if neither the top law rms nor Weil Gotshal are the
agents for change? We posit that multilevel interactions among attorneys and
between attorneys and judges in the pr ivate equity industry and, in particular,
at private equity and M&A confer ences, over time play an important role in
change. In such a collaborative model for change, we predict that there will
be many sep arate agents for change that both act independently and also learn
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1917
from each other. In this context, we predict that evolution will occur but in a
non-uniform way as dierent agents adopt varying types of change.
For the Limited Fraud provisions, we observe that there are several
dierent variations possible. West’s articles, building on Judge Strine’s ABRY
decision, did not merely urge private equity lawyers to narrowly dene fraud
to protect their sell side clients against what would be an unexpected liability.
He also explained precisely how fraud needed to be narrowly dened to
protect the private equity seller maximally. Simplifying, he had three sets of
instructions as to how fraud was to be narrowly dened. Failure to follow
these instructions could undermine the purpose behind eorts to dene
fraud. The provision needed to make clear:
that the fraud carve-out applied only to explicit factual representations
in the contract’s representations and warranties (or some other relevant
section) and not extra-contractual statements (“Scope”);
that the statements for which fraud claims could be brought were only
those of the individual private equity sellers and not their agents (e.g.,
management at the company they were trying to sell) (“Dene the Speaker”);
that fraud in question for which liability was being agreed to was only
intentional and knowing fraud; not reckless, negligent, constructive, or
common law fraud (“Intentional Fraud Only”).
105
If multilevel interactions drive change, we predict that adopted Limited
Fraud clauses will contain variation along these three dimensions, with
Limited Fraud clauses providing varying combinations of Scope, Dene the
Speaker, and Intentional Fraud Only. In contrast, if a more centralized force
drives the change, we predict that adopted Limited Fraud clauses will
converge on the form preferred by the central agent for change.
106
To examine variations in the deals with a fraud carve-out that include a
Limited Fraud clause, we track four dierent variations: deals with no Scope,
Dene the Speaker, or Intentional Fraud Only language recommended by
Glenn West (None), deals with only one of the three recommended additions
(One), deals with two of the three recommended additions (Two), and deals
105
ABRY Partners, 891 A.2d at 1063-64.
106
In a prior study of sovereign bonds, where there was an identiable set of change agents
coordinating an industry wide change, we found that a market where dierent actors who were using
dierent formulations of a problematic clause subsequently, after there was a coordinating event,
almost all moved to a single formulation of the clause. See Stephen J. Choi, Mitu Gulati & Robert
E. Scott, Variation in Boilerplate: Rational Design or Random Mutation?, 20 A
M. L. & ECON. REV. 1,
17 (2018).
1918 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
with all three recommended additions (All).
107
We tabulate in Table 5 the
number of deals in each of the four variations in dening fraud by year (with
2014 and earlier combined into a single year period).
107
In addition to this hand-coded approach to measuring variation in fraud denitions, we also
employed quantitative text analysis to study variation (namely, analyzing the “cosine similarity
among the fraud denitions in our dataset). The results of that complementary analysis, which are
unreported here, are consistent with the results below; dierent linguistic formulations in the
denition of fraud, as measured by the cosine similarity approach, persist over the duration of the
dataset.
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1919
Table 4: Variations in Deals with a Fraud Carve-Out that Include a
Limited Fraud Clause
None One Two All Total
2014 0 4 2 5 11
and
earlier 0.0 36.4 18.2 45.5 100.0
2015 0 2 2 2 6
0.0 33.3 33.3 33.3 100.0
2016 0 1 1 1 3
0.0 33.3 33.3 33.3 100.0
2017 1 4 5 1 11
9.1 36.4 45.5 9.1 100.0
2018 3 9 6 6 24
12.5 37.5 25.0 25.0 100.0
2019 5 6 5 10 26
19.2 23.1 19.2 38.5 100.0
2020 5 4 20 19 48
10.4 8.3 41.7 39.6 100.0
Total 14 30 41 44 129
10.9 23.3 31.8 34.1 100.0
Pearson chi-squared(18) = 14.7834 Pr = 0.677. For each year, we report the
number of deals in each of the four limited fraud provision variations and the
total number of deals. For each year, we also report the percent each variation
represents of the total deals in a given year.
1920 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
While the overall number of deals with a fraud carve-out th at also
included a Limited Fraud clause increased over time in our data sample, the
variation among dierent ty pes of Limited Fraud clauses did not diminish
over time. In 2020, Limited Fraud clauses consisted of: None (10.4 ), One
(8.3%), Two (41.7%), and All (39.6%). Not only is the form of the fraud
denition recommended by Glenn West (the All form) not the most
prevalent clause, but the incidence in 2020 (39.6%) is lower than the incidence
in the 2014 or earlier period (45.5%). Consistent with the persistent variation
in fraud denitions, from Table 4, a chi-squared test failed to reject the null
hypothesis that the distribution of the four dierent type s of fraud denitions
was dierent across the years.
108
While we observe variation in the denition of fraud in Limited Fraud
clauses overall, what about for deals with a Top Seller Law Firm? Even
though such rms are not the leaders in the adoption of a Limited Fraud
clause, perhaps when these rms do adopt a Limited Fraud term, they adopt
the gold standard version with All of the suggested variations by Glenn West.
To examine this possibility, we tabulate the number of deals in each of the
four variations in dening fraud for Top Seller Law Firms compared with
Other Seller Law Firms in Table 5.
108
Indeed, our methodology understates the amount of variation that exists in the fraud
denition. Our One category inclu des three dierent sub-variations: Scope alone (seven instances
in our sample), Dene the Speaker alone (eleven instances), and Intentional Fraud Only alone (eight
instances). Similarly, our Two category includes three dierent sub-variations: Scope + Dene the
Speaker (twenty-seven instances in our sample), Scope + Intentional Fraud Only (three instances),
and Dene the Speaker + Intentional Fraud Only (seven instances).
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1921
Table 5: Variations in Limited Fraud Denitions Between Top Seller Law
Firms and Other Seller Law Firms
T
yp
e of Variation
None One Two
A
ll Total
Other
Seller Law
Firm 12 23 33 35 103
11.7 22.3 32.0 34.0 100.0
To
p
Seller 2 5 6 7 20
Law Firm 10.0 25.0 30.0 35.0 100.0
Total 14 28 39 42 123
11.4 22.8 31.7 34.2 100.0
Pearson chi-squared(3) = 0.1196 Pr = 0.989.
For each category of law rms, we report the number of deals in each of the
four limited fraud provision variations and the total number of deals. For each
category of law rms, we also report the percent each variation represents of the
total deals in a given category.
From Table 5 note that Top Seller Law Firms use the All variation of the
Limited Fraud clause in roughly the same percentage (35.0%) as compared
with other seller law rms (34.0%). The percentages for the other variations
of the Limited Fraud clause are similar for the Top Seller Law Firms and
other law rms. Consistent with Top Seller Law Firms having a similar
amount of variation in the Limited Fraud clause as other seller law rms,
from Table 5, a chi-squared test failed to reject the null hypothesis that the
distribution of the four dierent types of Limited Fraud variations was
dierent across the two groups of seller law rms.
As one last test of whether the Top Seller Law Firms are more likely to
use the gold standard All var iation of the Limited Fraud clause, we look at
the sequence of Limited Fraud denitions adopted in deals over time in our
dataset where Kirkland & Ellis, the number one ranked private equity law
rm in the Vault 2020 rankings, was the seller law rm. Limited Fraud clauses
were found in eight deals where Kirkland & Ellis advised the seller over the
1922 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
course of our dataset.
109
Sometimes the robust All variation of the Limited
Fraud clause was employed, such as:
‘Fraud’ shall mean actual and intentional fraud with respect to the making of
the representations and warranties of a Seller pursuant to Section 2,
provided, however, that such actual and intentional fraud of such Seller shall
only be deemed to exist if such Seller had actual knowledge (as opposed to
imputed or constructive knowledge) that the representations and warranties
of such Seller pursuant to Section 2 were actually breached when made, with
the express intention that Purchaser rely thereon to its detriment.
110
At other times, a re latively spare denition limiting fraud was used:
“‘Fraud’ shall mean intentional and knowing common law fraud with the
intent to deceive regarding a misrepresentation in this Agreement or the
Tender and Support Agreement.
111
Figure 5 below depicts the variation of the Limited Fraud provisions in
the eight deals on which Kirkland & Ellis advised sellers over time, with
0=None, 1=One, 2=Two, and 3=All variations.
109
Whole Earth Brands, Inc. and WSO Investments, Inc., Stock Purchase Agreement (Dec.
17, 2020); Future Infrastructure Holdings, LLC and Primoris Services Corp., Agreement and Plan
of Merger (Dec. 14, 2020); NESCO Holdings II, Inc. and Blackstone Energy Partners NQ L.P.,
Purchase and Sale Agreement (Dec. 3, 2020); Stratus Video Holding Co. and AMN Healthcare,
Inc., Stock Purchase Agreement (Jan. 26, 2020); Archrock Services L.P. and Elite Compression
Services, LLC, Asset Purchase Agreement (June 23, 2019); Smart & Final Stores, Inc. and First
Street Parent, Inc., Agreement and Plan of Merger (Apr. 16, 2019); Coupa Software Inc. and Opus
Global Holdings, LLC, Purchase Agreement (Dec. 4, 2018); Adobe Systems Inc. and Vista Equity
Partners, Share Purchase Agreement (Sept. 20, 2018).
110
Adobe Systems, Inc., supra note 108.
111
Smart & Final Stores, Inc., supra note 108.
2023] Contract Production in M&A Markets 1923
Figure 5: Limited Fraud Provisions in Deals with Kirkland & Ellis as
Seller Law Firm
Even for deals with the same Top Seller Law Firm, Kirkland & Ellis, there
is considerable variation in the denition of fraud over time. The rst deal
with Kirkland & Ellis as the seller law rm contains the All variation.
However, the next three deals contain a mixture of the One and Two
variations. After another All variation, the last three deals, all in 2020, contain
the Two variation for the Limited Fraud clause. Over a span of eight deals,
Kirkland & Ellis as the seller’s attorney rm corresponded with th ree of the
four variations of the Limited Fraud clause. This nding is inconsistent with
the top law rms acting as a central agent of change in contracting languag e
for private equity deals (where we would expect one form— the Gold
Standard All form—to be uniform among the top law rms).
We also examined Weil Gotshal acting as the seller’s attorney. Weil
Gotshal, however, was involved in only one deal with a Limited Fraud term
in our dataset that occurred in January 2014. While the Limited Fraud term
from this one deal was th e All variation, we do not think it plausible that Weil
Gotshal was the driving force behind change given the lack of any Limited
Fraud term in the eight subsequent deals with Weil Gotshal as the seller’s
attorney that contained a fraud carve- out after January 2014 in our dataset.
1924 University of Pennsylvania Law Review [Vol. 171: 1881
CONCLUSION
For many years, schol ars have well understood that standard form
contracts in thick markets such as those for corporate and sovereign bonds
evolve dierently than those in markets using bespoke contracts. And that
dierential evolution ows from the reality that contract producers in these
markets, while seeking to optimize, are engaged in dierent processe s from
producers in more bespoke deals. Bespoke contracting in thin markets yields,
at least in theory, ecient design of contract terms but at a considerable
expenditure in production costs. Production costs are substantially reduced
in large liquid markets such as the sovereign and corporate bond markets that
rely on universally adopted standardized terms. But these markets are
characterized by ineciencies in design: they lack systematic means of
coordinating to produce ecient changes in contract language. The world of
private M&A deals sits between the two poles of bespoke and boilerplate
deals and exhibits features of both. This article seeks to add to our
understanding of the contract production process by examining this hybrid
world.
Participants in the private M&A market display a preference for both the
option to have bespoke terms and the ability to deploy standardized terms.
This intermediate preference leads to a market structure conducive to organic
coordination. The lawyers drafting these M&A agreements, and particularly
private equity M&A deals, belong to a network of practitioners that meet
frequently at conferences, often together with the judges who decide litigated
cases, to discuss and debate new developments. Using both qualitative and
quantitative data, we nd evidence of an informal information network.
Consisting of judicial opinions, writings of elite lawyers, bar association
meetings, and continuing education seminars, this network transforms
bespoke changes in contract design into industry-wide standard provisions.
The organic coordination structure leads to both market wide coordination
over a contract term following a change in the case law as well as a diversity
in this response as individual actors exercise their option to implement
bespoke variations of a new standard.
We do not claim to fully understand the mechanisms through which this
information system func tions. Indeed, much more remains to be learned
about how contracting parties in dierent markets optimize the various costs
of contract design and production.